CHEAP SPEECH AND WHAT IT WILL DO (How computer technology will transform the media) by Eugene Volokh<*>, VESOFT/UCLA Presented (KEY-NOTE) at 1995 SCRUG Conference, Irvine, CA Published by The Yale Law Journal, May 1995. Introduction It's easier for the rich to speak than it is for the poor. It's also easier to speak if what you're saying, or singing or drawing, has mass appeal. Publishers will only invest in a product if the expected returns exceed the expected costs. If your work lacks a wide audience, publishers may be hard to find; and even if you can get a small publisher to back you, distributors may be unwilling to let you use their scarce shelf space. Getting access to nationwide radio and TV is harder still. People with unorthodox tastes lose out, and even those in the mainstream suffer when potentially interesting work isn't produced because of (rational) predictions that it won't be a hit. Many have pointed to these problems -- the bias in favor of speech of the rich, or of speech endorsed by the rich, and the relative blandness of much mass media.<1> The perfect "marketplace of ideas" is one where all ideas, not just the popular or well- funded ones, are accessible to all. To the extent this ideal isn't achieved, the promise of the First Amendment is only imperfectly realized. And, some suggest, because current First Amendment doctrine is premised on an open-market metaphor that isn't valid, the law should be adapted to this brutal reality.<2> My thesis is that (1) these two problems are directly linked to the fact that speaking today is expensive; (2) new information technologies, especially the "information superhighway"<3> or "infobahn,"<4> will dramatically reduce the costs of distributing speech; and, therefore, (3) the new media order these technologies will bring will be much more democratic and diverse than the environment we see now. Cheap speech will mean that far more speakers -- rich and poor, popular and not, banal and avant-garde -- will be able to make their work available to all. To support this view, I will, in Part I, describe what I think will be the likely information future and the market forces that will make it inevitable. I'll focus on how the infobahn will change the existing forms of communication: music, books, newspapers, magazines, and television. (Though the new, truly interactive media -- electronic bulletin boards, Internet mailing lists, and Internet news groups -- are an extremely intriguing topic, lack of space keeps me from discussing them.<5>) In Part II, I'll suggest some social consequences of these technological changes, each of which might be relevant to thinking about the First Amendment: (1) {Democratization and Diversification:} Many more people will be able to make their speech widely available, including many who can't afford to do so today; and listeners will have much more choice than they have now. (2) {The Shift of Power Away from the Intermediaries:} Control over what is said and heard will shift from the intermediaries -- publishers, book and music store owners, and so on -- to the speakers and listeners themselves. Private parties will thus find it harder to use their market power to stifle speech. Listeners will find it easier to become well-informed about the issues in which they're interested. On the other hand, it will be easier for people to choose only the information they know they want, and to ignore other topics and other viewpoints. And the extra diversity of speech may reduce social and cultural cohesion. (3) {Mixed Effects on Poor Listeners:} Poor listeners will be able to enjoy many of the benefits of the new order, but may to some extent be shut out from other benefits. (4) {Substantial Changes in Advertising in the Media:} There'll be more no-advertising and low-advertising media; advertising will be better targeted to people; newspapers will lose a lot of classified advertising income; and political advertisements might change significantly. Finally, in Part III, I'll briefly explore some of the possible First Amendment implications of these changes. My ultimate conclusion is that the First Amendment of today will not only work well with the new information order -- it will work better than it ever has before. But I'll also discuss ways in which the new technologies might undercut some of the assumptions that underlie the existing doctrine, and might lead to public pressure for legal changes. I. Cheap Speech A. Music and the Electronic Music Databases 1. The New System a. What It Will Look Like I want to start by discussing how the new technologies will change popular music. These changes may be less politically momentous than the similar changes that I think will happen in print and video. But the music industry will probably be the one that changes most quickly; and in any case many of the things I say in this section -- about cost savings, increased choice, information overload, and so on -- will apply equally well to the others. The reasons for the changes will be very simple: There's lots of money in them. The existing music distribution system is inefficient, both for consumers and for musicians. For consumers, in particular, it has three problems: {Cost:} Music costs more than it could -- consumers must pay about $8-$15 for a new album, though musicians generally see less than 10% of this in royalties.<6> {Choice:} Consumers get a smaller selection than they could -- many titles, especially ones that are relatively old or that appeal to relatively small markets, aren't available in most places. {Convenience:} To buy music, a consumer has to take the time and trouble to go to the store. And these problems translate into problems for musicians. High cost, low availability, and inconvenience of buying mean fewer sales.<7> These inefficiencies aren't the result of some sinister plot or even of market irrationality. They are an inevitable consequence of the existing distribution system. People today must buy music on some tangible medium, such as tape or CD. This means they generally have to go to the music store (inconvenient), which has only limited shelf space (lowering the choice). And the tangible medium has to be created, imprinted, distributed, and sold (costly). The infobahn, once it delivers high-speed two-way communications to private homes, is a far superior way of delivering music to the consumer. It will work something like this: (1) Using your computer -- or perhaps your TV set, with a keyboard, a touch-screen, a mouse, or even voice activation -- you access an electronic music database. This database (actually, there'll probably be several competing databases) will contain virtually all the music that's available in electronic form. (2) You choose the music you want, by album name, by song title, by artist, by composer or songwriter, or by genre. You might even ask the computer for suggestions, based on the artists or albums you tell it you like. (This would be done using judgments entered into the computer by reviewers.) You can also browse in some way, perhaps looking only at music of a particular kind, or music that has gotten good reviews. You can then play the music, to make sure you really want to buy it.<8> (3) Once you decide you like it, you download the album to a digital recorder connected to your computer. Your bank account gets automatically debited. This would mean: {Cost:} Once the music is recorded -- which even nowadays costs fairly little<9> -- the only significant other costs will be advertising costs, royalties, the cost of electronic distribution, and the cost of the recording medium (which will be supplied by the customer). There'll be no need to spend money to create the tangible recordings, ship them, and sell them. Assuming cheap electronic transmission (an assumption I'll try to back up shortly), a CD-quality album may well cost as little as $3 to $5 -- a $1 royalty,<10> plus amortization of the recording costs and advertising costs, plus the $1 or $2 that the customer will have to pay for the recording medium. An artist who's willing to pocket less money to get more customers might be able to charge $3 or less. {Choice:} You'll have close to the whole music library of the world at your disposal. Copyright owners will be able to sell to any infobahn-connected consumers, not just to the ones who have access to a store that's willing to stock the work. Because there'll be no shelf-space limitation -- computer storage is cheap, and getting more so -- it won't matter how esoteric your tastes are; there'll be room for nearly everything.<11> {Convenience:} You'll no longer have to drive to the music store or wait in line. You'll also be able to select what you want more conveniently, because you'll be able to easily pre-listen to what you're buying,<12> and because you'll have readily available reviews. The copyright owners will benefit from this, too, because whenever consumers read a good review or like a song they hear on the radio, they'll be able to buy the music instantly, or at most have to wait until they get home. b. Why It Will Look Like This {Music Database Operators:} There's a lot of money to be made here. In the United States alone, there were 425 million albums sold in the first six months of 1994,<13> at an average cost of over $10 each, including both the more expensive CDs and the cheaper, lower sound quality tapes. The sales volume should increase as costs go down, and the convenience of buying the product from home should raise volume even more. Skimming even, say, ten cents per transaction would mean, at today's rates, almost $100 million yearly. Mail-order CD catalogs -- including computerized ones, such as {cdconnection.com,} which is accessible either directly through your modem or through the Internet<14> -- are already the first step towards the system I describe. They attract customers by offering a large selection,<15> slightly lower prices,<16> and the convenience of home shopping, partly countered by the inconvenience of having to wait for the CDs to arrive by mail.<17> Direct downloading should provide even greater cost savings, selection, and convenience. Setting up a music database shouldn't be much harder than starting a mail-order CD business today; and it should be much easier than starting a chain of music stores. Like the U.S. Mail, the telephone system, or the Internet, the infobahn should let any business be accessible through it.<18> The database operators will have to buy computer equipment and design some software, but this shouldn't cost much. Even a database operator who gets only, say, 1% of the total market can make almost $10 million yearly by charging a $1 mark-up (which will still save consumers a lot of money). Ten million transactions yearly -- thirty thousand daily -- can easily be handled even today with relatively cheap equipment.<19> And the low cost of setting up a database should keep competition high and consumer prices low. {Copyright Owners:} There's also profit here for copyright owners. The new system will let copyright owners exploit markets that were closed to them before: people who would pay, say, $5 for electronic delivery of an album but not $10 for the album in the store (cost);<20> people who didn't have access to stores that stock the album (choice); and people who otherwise wouldn't have taken the trouble to go the record store, or who had meant to buy an album they heard on the radio but had forgotten about it by the time they got to the store (convenience). The electronic database operators would easily be able to pay the copyright owners royalties as high as what the owners get from music store sales, if that's what it takes to get the owners to sign up. This will become especially true when, as some copyright owners join, others will also find themselves pushed to join by competitive pressures. Once even a few albums become available for $5 rather than $10, albums that sell for $10 will be at a significant disadvantage. Though music isn't fungible -- loyal fans of New Kids on the Block might not think Tom Waits an adequate substitute -- some product substitution will doubtless occur.<21> {Consumers:} As I mentioned in the previous section, consumers can also benefit greatly from the new system. True, any change -- especially one involving computerization -- risks alienating customers, but the new system can be made very user- friendly.<22> The system needn't be any harder to use than an ATM; and, as with the ATM, which has probably saved billions of person- lunch-hours per year, the new system's benefits should be substantial enough that people will learn to use it. Moreover, the physical advantages of music store layout -- the ability to browse, and the possibility that one will stumble over something good that one hadn't even thought of buying -- can be made available on the home computer, too. The software can easily have a general "Browse" (or "Browse The Kind Of Music I Like") feature, if this is what the users want. The software can also have other useful features -- such as a convenient pre-listen mode, or cross-references to reviews<23> -- that many music stores do not have. And if people really need human help, the software can, at the touch of a button, switch to a voice connection with an operator at the central database location.<24> {Technology:} The new setup will require a good deal of new technology, but what's not here yet is coming soon. There's already music being sent through the Internet.<25> Digitally recorded music is simply a collection of data, no different (from the computer's point of view) from your WordPerfect document. There's no reason it can't be sent down the wires to your home.<26> Once the music arrives -- in data form -- at your home, it will need to be recorded on some high-quality medium.<27> Two familiar media are nonstarters: Normal analog audiotape is too low-quality, and CDs are read-only. But two recently introduced technologies -- digital compact cassettes (DCCs) and MiniDiscs -- might have what it takes. They both provide sound quality as good as that of a CD; you should be able to download music to them from your home computer, and then play it at home, in your car, or in your Walkman. Today they cost a lot,<28> but prices are expected to fall with new innovations and economies of scale,<29> just as they did for normal CD equipment.<30> To use this system, people will need a computer, but there are already an estimated 30 million home computers installed today.<31> The cheapest ones now cost about $700,<32> and, of course, this money will buy you many more features than just home music delivery. Moreover, even people who can't afford a home computer and a home digital recorder might still use the system through public music vending machines. These machines may cost more than the home versions, because they'll need to be more resilient (and probably more theft- and vandalism-proof); a fragile keyboard interface might have to be replaced by a touch-screen interface, or by something similarly robust. Still, this shouldn't be especially difficult or expensive -- consider ATMs, video games, and public lottery ticket machines. So long as there are millions of people who don't have home computers and home digital recorders, there'll be plenty of incentive to tap this market. And some music stores already have computerized music catalog machines (called Muzes)<33> -- the music vending machines would basically be that, plus an infobahn hookup, a credit or debit card reader, and a recorder. Finally, it shouldn't be a problem to charge people electronically for using the service. The system could ask for a credit card number when you access it -- much as is done today for phone sales, or for {cdconnection.com} computer sales -- and get it confirmed while you're shopping. Better yet, it could charge you through your infobahn provider, much as 900 numbers now charge through the phone company. Music vending machines could accept credit cards or debit cards. And even more convenient forms of electronic payment may soon be available; electronic payment could be a boon to many businesses, and the market demand for it has generated a good deal of research and investment.<34> 2. How the New System Will Change What Is Available The new distribution technology will do more than just make music cheaper and easier to get. It will also radically change {what} music is available. I've already mentioned one way this will happen: The music databases will provide access to albums that stores otherwise wouldn't stock. Even if there are 50,000 fans of a particular kind of music throughout the country, a music store might expect there to be only a handful of these people among its customers. It can't afford to use shelf space for material that appeals to so few people. But electronic databases can carry even albums that appeal to only a tiny fraction of the market. The result will be more diversity for the listeners (even if not all of them may take advantage of this diversity). But electronic home distribution will do more than eliminate the bottleneck of music stores. It will also greatly reduce the power of the music production companies (the "labels"). Electronic distribution will drastically lower up-front distribution costs. Even today an artist can make a commercially viable master recording for as little as $1000.<35> With electronic distribution, once the master is made, no more money needs to be spent on tangible copy production, distribution, or sales. An artist will no longer have to persuade a production company that his product is worth the investment. He'll be able to create it himself and submit it to the electronic databases; and once it's in the databases, the work will be as available as if it were in every music store in the country. Many artists will probably still prefer that someone else pay for recording and editing the album (especially if they want a more-frills recording), and they'd probably like to have someone invest in advertising. Labels will thus still survive, and the artists will still have to persuade the labels that their works will sell enough to justify the investment. But the needed investment will be much less than it is today. Less money will have to be recouped, so the labels will be more willing to back material that has a small likely audience. And even if no one is willing to invest, the artists may still be able to pay for the recording themselves, go without advertising, and hope it sells through word of mouth, good reviews, or radio play (especially the custom-mix radio, which I describe below). Advertising is better for the artist than no advertising; but even no advertising is better than the current system, where without a label an artist essentially can't make the music available to the public at all. 3. Dealing with Information Overload The great obstacle to consumers getting what they want will no longer be that there are too few products available; it will be that there are too many. The new system, by reducing barriers to entry, will make much more material available to consumers. Some of it will be good; most will be junk. This, of course, isn't a new problem. Tens of thousands of books and CDs come out yearly. Most of us have had the experience of going to the store and not knowing what to buy. But we've made do, largely because the information overload has spawned professionals -- reviewers, radio programmers, and decisionmakers at the record stores and the labels -- who help us wade through the material. These people's job is to find what they think we'll most like, and tell us about it, play it for us so we can decide for ourselves, or try to sell it to us. The new system will reduce the role of the record stores and the labels, but the other sources of information will remain. Rather than sending its work to production companies, hoping for a contract, a musical group will send it to reviewers. The reviewers will probably specialize in particular genres, and there will probably be quite a few of them, of varying reputations. Some of these reviewers will, like music reviewers today, write for newspapers, magazines, and such.<36> Other reviewers will select albums that they recommend and e-mail sample songs to their clients. The clients will then be able to listen to the songs at their leisure, and, if they like what they hear, buy the album (perhaps after first listening to the whole album) at the touch of a few keys. Still other reviewers will write brief reviews -- perhaps even just give numerical ratings -- for the music databases; they might also compare the music to other albums or artists.<37> This will let database customers search for, say, "New Reggae that has gotten a thumbs up from at least two reviewers," or "Songs that someone who likes Tom Waits might enjoy." This class of reviewers will probably be paid by the music database operators.<38> {Custom-Mix Cable Radio:} The most valuable review service, though, will be something akin to cable radio today. The virtue of radio as a selection tool is that it's outside your control, and can therefore familiarizes you with material you didn't know about. This, of course, is also its vice. You have some selection over what's played -- you can listen to a given station or a given show. But the selection is limited. Even in a big radio market you might find that no station quite satisfies you. What one would optimally want, I believe, is to specify the radio mix more precisely, without sacrificing the element of the unexpected and new that radio can provide. One would like to be able to say, for instance: "I'd like a mix of '60s rock, rock ballads from all decades, bluegrass, songs recommended by a {Rolling Stone} reviewer, and songs that someone who likes the Talking Heads, Paul Simon, and Concrete Blonde might like. I'd also like a small part of the mix to be random rock. And {no Steely Dan!}"<39> People would prefer this approach because it maximizes the chances that they'll like what they'll hear. One doesn't have to be particularly musically literate to know roughly what one enjoys, and to want to hear more of it. It should be easy to get such a mix piped into your home. You could configure your preferences on your computer, and when you choose "home radio" mode, the computer would pick up a semi-random mix from the electronic databases and play it for you. Within the boundaries set by your preferences, the music would be selected based on the reviews stored in the databases. Because you can pay for the music directly, you'll have the option of either a free service with commercials, or a paid service with no commercials. There's no reason to think the paid service would be very expensive, since there'll be no transmitter and FCC license to amortize, and since the copyright owners, interested in selling albums, will likely charge little for the rights. Cable radio is already available in some markets, though of course without the preference configuration system; it costs $5 to $10 per month.<40> You could also set up your computer to automatically store a mix every morning onto a DCC or a MiniDisc; then, you could take it into your car and play it all day in place of wireless radio.<41> It might be a bit of a bother for a person to pop in a new cassette or disc every night and take it to the car every morning. Nonetheless, the extra effort on the consumer's part shouldn't be prohibitive, especially if investing this effort could substantially increase listening pleasure.<42> If a reviewer has 10,000 subscribers -- and recall that the market is nationwide -- he can make a decent living charging them $5 to $10 {a year,} plus copyright clearance costs, for a custom- mix service based on his reviews. Even with 1000 subscribers, the reviewer can make some money for not very hard work. Alternatively, reviewers can accept advertising, or take money from people who want their material reviewed. Some people might not trust reviewers paid by the musicians,<43> but subscribers will be able to choose between those reviewers paid by musicians, those paid by subscribers, and those funded by advertising.<44> Of course, like the other screening mechanisms, this will give some people -- no longer the labels but now the reviewers -- some power over what people will hear. A band that once complained "Our music is brilliant but the producers are keeping it off the market" will instead say "Our music is brilliant but the reviewers can't appreciate it." The power of reviewers, though, is based on people's approval of their tastes. Maybe the people's trust is misplaced, but it's hard for artists to complain that the reviewers' power is illegitimate. Moreover, the reviewers' power is much less exclusionary than the power of the labels: If I don't like one reviewer's taste, I can easily switch to another; if reviewers are neglecting material that at least some listeners -- even small groups of listeners -- would like, other reviewers will step into the breach; and the low costs of providing reviews mean even small markets will have many reviewers serving them. Though there might ultimately be thousands of reviewers providing their own custom-mix services, I doubt this will cause much of a reviewer overload problem. Reviewers will probably specialize in particular genres or subgenres. Within those genres, people will probably start with the most popular or best advertised mix. People who are satisfied with their custom-mix service will stick with it; people who aren't will easily be able to try someone else, perhaps someone their friends recommend. 4. Will Production Companies Go Along? I mentioned above that electronic music databases will succeed because both copyright owners and consumers can benefit from them. But many sound recording copyrights are owned by the music production companies. If, as I suggest, production companies will be hurt by the new system, will they be willing to license copyrights to businesses that will likely displace them? Production companies may well be reluctant to let the electronic music databases get off the ground; but it seems to me competitive pressures will ultimately force them to go along. The new system gives copyright owners a new way of exploiting markets they otherwise couldn't reach. Even if it will prove generally bad for labels in the long term, some small labels -- which may have their sights set more on selling their existing stock rather than on the long run -- will want to take advantage of it. Musicians signing new recording deals may want to take advantage of it, too, because the new system is definitely in their interest; and if the musician has a good enough bargaining position, the label may have to participate even if it doesn't really want to. Also, the fact that copyrights in musical works aren't truly exclusive may play a role. A musician can make a recording of a song without the composer's permission, so long as he pays a compulsory royalty (today, 6.6 cents per song per copy).<45> A musician can even intentionally try to make his performance sound just like another musician's performance, so long as he doesn't physically copy the other's recording.<46> Of course, people might still much prefer the Beatles' {Let It Be} to Volokh-trying-to- sound-like-the-Beatles' {Let It Be}; but the fact that new covers of old standards constantly come out will weaken somewhat the copyright monopolist's hold on the market. Finally, once the system gets off the ground, the lower cost and extra convenience to consumers will lead to pressure for reluctant labels to participate. Even consumers who today are willing to pay $10 for albums at stores may become reluctant to do this once they get used to paying $5 from home. I recognize this is speculation -- this is a speculative article -- but it seems this situation isn't that far off from classic market competition. To take an analogous case, prices often fall not because the existing market players prefer that they fall, but because new entrants, or small vendors looking for market share, drive the prices down. While large producers may try to stop this, they generally can't. B. Books, Magazines, and Newspapers 1. Introduction Text is even easier to send electronically than music, because it requires a good deal less space, and therefore less transmission time; it can even be transmitted feasibly through today's relatively slow communications mechanisms. Some newspapers already put much of their news online.<47> And there are already special electronic-only news services, such as Clarinet Communications' {ClariNews,} which contains everything from business news to sports to a few columnists (such as Miss Manners) and cartoons (such as {Dilbert} and {Bizarro}).<48> There are also libraries of electronic books. Project Gutenberg at Illinois Benedictine College has created a database of 160 books, including the Bible, {Alice in Wonderland,} and the collected works of Shakespeare, all available free on the Internet.<49> The Internet Bookstore service sells new books from various publishers, including Paramount MacMillan, Oxford University Press, and the National Review. The books sell for about one-third of the print price, and take about 30 seconds to download.<50> The problem, of course, is that computer screens are harder to read than books. Modern large-screen workstations, with black-on- white display and proportionally spaced fonts, are better than the old 24-by-80 non-graphical displays that most of us still use. Still, they're not as easy to read as a book, and they certainly aren't as portable. There are two ways to deal with this: Some text might be not only electronically delivered, but also printed out on home printers; and laptop computers might be made so readable and portable that reading text on them will be as easy as reading a book. I'll deal with these two possibilities in turn. 2. Short Opinion Articles and Home Printers I suggested above that, in the coming years, more and more homes will have a computer, an infobahn connection, and probably a music recorder connected to the computer. But even more common than the recorder will be the laser printer. Laser printers can generate text that's as readable as what you see in a newspaper; today they cost as little as $400.<51> And while people probably wouldn't like hundreds of unbound, single-sided, 8 1/2"x11" sheets of paper coming off their printers -- which is what would be required for a complete book or newspaper -- one to five sheets should be no problem. There are lots of people who make a living writing short, periodic articles. There are columnists, either daily or weekly, such as William Safire, Mike Royko, and the like. There are comic strip artists. There are also organizations, such as the ACLU, the NRA, and many smaller ones, which periodically send out their ideas -- or at least would like to send out their ideas -- to their members or fellow travelers. Electronic delivery, assuming it's cheap enough, is a perfect medium for these writers and their readers. The set-up would be simple: (1) A consumer will run a program on his home computer that will show him a list of available columns. This list would be indexed by author, by topic, and so on. (2) He can then choose the column he wants; the cost of the subscription will be automatically transferred from his account to the writer's. (3) Every night, or once every week, a column will be sent to his computer, which will automatically print it.<52> The writers win under this system, because they can reach readers they never could otherwise: people in areas where no newspaper carries their column, and people who don't subscribe to a newspaper. Moreover, by cutting out the middleman, a columnist may be able to get more per subscriber than he does today. Readers win for the same reasons. Electronic delivery is also perfect for the public interest organizations. Today, they have to communicate with people by mail, a costly proposition.<53> If the infobahn dramatically cuts the cost, they can increase their impact by writing to their members more often, and by reaching nonmembers, too. If, say, delivering three or four pages costs five cents, the ACLU could offer people a weekly "ACLU Action Letter" for $2.50 a year. Millions of sympathizers might well want to subscribe at that rate, especially if they could do so in minutes from their home computers. {Technology:} There's every reason to think the cost of transmitting the text will be extremely low. Two information infrastructures of today may be useful analogies: According to a recent estimate, the cost of transmitting 2000 bytes (about a page of uncompressed text) even using today's relatively primitive Internet technology is about 1/6 of a cent;<54> and local phone calls are already free.<55> As newer, faster delivery methods come online, the cost of transmission should fall even below that of the Internet. The big expense will probably be paper. Paper nowadays costs about 1 cent per page.<56> A daily one-page column might thus cost the consumer as little as 2 cents a day -- one cent for the paper and one for the transmission cost and profit for the sender; this comes to less than $10 a year. The per-item paper costs will go down if the consumer subscribes to more than one item, since the computer can fit several columns or comics onto one page. And even if the transmission costs are somewhat higher, the result might still be quite affordable. {Consumer Satisfaction:} Consumers should also be satisfied with this format. Print quality should be up to snuff; subscribing will be easy; the columns will arrive automatically on the printer, with no extra keys to punch every morning. Some people might actually prefer a few pages of their favorite stuff to a thick newspaper they must unfold and search through. Of course, some people may be unwilling to pay even pennies for the columns. They may already be subscribing to a local paper, which is chock full of columns and cartoons and lots of other things. After paying $100 to $200 a year for the subscription,<57> they may not want to pay more. Nonetheless, the great majority of people do {not} subscribe to newspapers. Many of them might not much like print, but others don't want all the data newspapers provide -- they may find it irrelevant, or they might get it from radio when they drive to work, or they might not have time to read the newspaper every day. They might well prefer paying, say, $25 a year for the few columns and comics they really like. And even people who already subscribe to newspapers may be willing to pay that much for the columns the newspaper doesn't carry. Twenty-five dollars a year is cheap as entertainment goes, especially when it's entertainment that the reader knows he'll enjoy, and that he can easily subscribe to on a whim. Some people may be deterred by the cost, but lots will not be. {Speaker Willingness:} Finally, there should be no shortage of willing high-quality speakers. Public interest organizations should be happy to use this medium, and there's every reason to believe they can provide quality (if partisan) commentary to their subscribers. Existing columnists might be a somewhat different matter. William Safire and Judith Martin (Miss Manners), for instance, already appear in hundreds of newspapers. Their syndication agreements may contain exclusivity clauses ensuring that the columns won't appear in more than one newspaper in each market. These newspapers might be reluctant to let these columns appear electronically in the same markets that the newspapers serve. Nonetheless, competitive pressures should eventually make more and more of the good columnists electronically available. To begin with, columns could be distributed with geographic restrictions: You can subscribe if you're in Las Vegas but not if you're in Los Angeles. Columnists can thus give their newspapers exclusivity, while still taking advantage of markets in which their columns otherwise wouldn't run. Newspapers might be hesitant to go along even with this scheme; the electronic distribution system competes with newspapers as a medium, and newspapers may be reluctant to give any edge to their competitor. But recall that every subscriber for a one-cent daily column could be $3 a year in a columnist's pocket. If there are 100,000 extra subscribers the columnist thinks he can reach -- and there are millions of people who read (not just have access to) the highest-profile columnists -- that's a couple of hundred thousand dollars. Persuading columnists to forgo this market could be an expensive proposition for newspapers. Some newspapers might be able to get some columnists to agree not to publish electronically; more might be able to get them to limit distribution to places where the columns are unavailable in print. But not all newspapers would be able or willing to do this in the face of the substantial economic pressure on the columnist to go electronic. Moreover, good opinion pieces aren't expensive to produce. Not everyone can consistently write informative, readable prose, but neither is the talent remarkably rare. There are probably tens of thousands of people who could do the task. With the electronic medium, each of them will be able to throw his hat in the ring. If the Safires and the Martins don't do it, others will. Of course, they'll have to find their audience, in competition with thousands of others. But finding this audience electronically may be easier than finding a comparable audience with newspapers; and even if most columnists fail, that'll just be because others will succeed. {The Survival of Newspaper Columns:} Note that, unlike record stores -- which I think will be largely displaced by the electronic music databases -- opinion columns in newspapers will survive. People will still buy newspapers for news and will expect to get their familiar columnists, too. Moreover, an up-and-coming columnist may still prefer to be accepted by a newspaper, with potential access to millions of readers, instead of trying to find his own following on the electronic services. My claim is only that there will be a thriving electronic opinion column market parallel to the newspapers. 3. Ebooks and Books, Magazines, and Newspapers Home printers, however, will become less necessary once computer screens are developed that are roughly as readable, portable, and lightweight as books. One possibility, which I call an ebook, would be a display that is the size of a small book, folds open like a book, and has the resolution of a book. The technology isn't there yet, but it seems within reach.<58> You'd connect the ebook to your main computer and download a book from an electronic database to your ebook. Then you'd read it as you would a normal book, but pushing a button instead of flipping pages. There'd be ways, of course, to do all the normal "features" of a book -- go to a particular page, set a bookmark, highlight some text, write a note to yourself on the margin, and so on.<59> And there'd be other features normal books don't have: * You could search a book for a particular word or concept much more easily than with traditional indexes. * Foreign-language books would have built-in dictionaries. * You could easily carry around hundreds of books; the only limit will be the distribution of the material.<64> A {Newsweek} could deliver news to people that's genuinely current, rather than two or three days out of date. Newspapers will be able to update their stories as news comes in, and will no longer have to be up to a day behind broadcasters. Again, this will help the consumer as well as the publisher; and once some publishers do this, competitive pressures will push others to follow. Finally, ebooks will give newspaper publishers access to geographical markets that are now closed to them. Today, only the {New York Times,} the {Wall Street Journal,} {USA Today,} and the {Christian Science Monitor} have national home delivery.<65> Ebooks will open the whole country, and eventually the whole developed world, to all newspaper publishers. While many regional newspapers won't get much benefit from this, would-be national publications -- say, the {Washington Post,} or a liberal equivalent of the {Wall Street Journal}, or the entertainment section of the {L.A. Times} -- certainly would; and so would some foreign newspapers, which have a ready market of expatriates and others who are professionally or personally interested in the foreign country.<66> {Technology:} The ebook would cost much more than a typical book. The cheapest laptop displays wholesale today for about $1100, with the price supposed to fall shortly to as little as $500 or $700.<67> The price will probably fall further, but it seems likely it will always remain fairly high. One could easily save that much, though, in lower costs for the actual literary works themselves. Working from a customary 10- 15% royalty,<68> and including a mark-up for editorial services and electronic database costs, books that sell today for $5 to $20 could sell for as little as $1 to $4 each.<69> And, of course, the reader will save the costs of driving to the bookstore, trying to track down a book that isn't on the shelves, and finding that the book he wants is out of print. Scanning old books into computers is hard, but virtually all new books published today must be put into electronic form in order to be printed. Publishers can easily send all new books to an electronic database, so any infobahn-connected home will be able to access them. The ebook wouldn't have the feel of a conventional book, even if it has the look. People who like feeling paper rather than plastic under their fingertips may always loathe ebooks, or so I've heard from friends with whom I've discussed this concept. On the other hand, people might prefer ebooks to bulky, hard- to-unfold, ink-smearing newspapers. And while some people will always appreciate paper books (though probably not all paper books) as objects of art, the main purpose of books is to communicate information. The ebook will, I think, be useful enough that many people raised on paper books will switch to it. But even those who wouldn't read it for themselves would buy it for their children, especially given the possible educational benefits of interactive ebooks. And the children, when they grow up, might not be as nostalgic for paper books as today's adults may be. 4. How the New Media Will Change What Is Available a. More Diversity Even more than with music, the lower distribution costs will change what is available, as well as how it's available. High distribution costs have meant media organs -- newspapers, magazines, radio stations, TV stations -- control which commentators are available and which aren't. They control based on their own political opinions, and they also control based on what their readers are likely to want. Even if, say, a million people nationwide may want to hear the Libertarian -- or Socialist -- view of things, there may be too few such people in each major market to make it worthwhile for newspapers to carry columns that appeal to these readers. Lower distribution costs mean columnists and organizations can thrive if they appeal to even as few as several thousand people. Say columns cost cent for transmission, 1 cent for paper, and cent for royalties to the author. If even 30,000 people nationwide are willing to subscribe to a daily column -- for about $7.50 a year -- the columnist will make $150 a day, enough to keep body and soul together. An organization like the ACLU, which might get 1 million subscribers, can make $3.5 million yearly on these terms, enough to hire editors, writers, and news gatherers, and perhaps even fund the organization's other public interest activities. Poor speakers will get a soapbox; listeners with unusual tastes will find more material that will please them; and the mix of available commentary will be much less bland than it is today. The same will happen for books. The new technologies will make books cheaper and largely eliminate the problem of books being out-of-print, but they'll also allow more books to be published. Publication, in fact, will consist simply of the writer sending the book to some electronic databases. There'll be no publisher, no veto power on the publisher's part, and no need for the book to have mass appeal before someone will invest in it. The story for newspapers and magazines will be somewhat different. Though their distribution costs will fall, their production costs will still be substantial. The news will still have to be gathered, written up, and edited. But the total costs will be lower than they'd otherwise be, so publications will be easier to start and easier to keep profitable. {Some Examples:} Electronically distributed short newsletters already exist today, though -- for technological reasons -- not yet in the form I describe. Fax newsletters are already used for timely, relatively low-cost distribution. (Though faxing may cost money for phone calls, it saves labor costs -- stuffing envelopes, printing labels, and the like -- because it can be done automatically by computer.) Bankruptcy Creditors' Service sends specialized newsletters to creditors of debtors-in-possession.<70> {The Thoroughbred Daily News} circulates a daily delivered-by-6-am newsletter summarizing the previous day's racing.<71> These services are expensive, but that seems to be just a function of what the market will bear. There's no reason they can't be cheaper if the author and the customers so prefer: Some religious organizations, for instance, have started free religious fax newsletters for their congregants.<72> Westlaw is another example. Westlaw has several databases -- WLB (West's Law Bulletin), WTH-CJ (West's Topical Highlights on Criminal Justice), WTH-LB (Highlights on Labor Law), and others -- which West updates daily with one-paragraph squibs on potentially important recent cases. The cases range from a few days to a few weeks old. Using Westlaw's PDQ (Personal Directory of Queries) service, I've asked that new additions to those databases be printed daily to my local printer. I've also configured special queries of my own, for instance to every day print all new cases on free exercise of religion. Each morning, I go to the printer and get new information that I might otherwise have never seen. It's like a daily newspaper chock full of articles for legal junkies like me. Of course, this would cost me a fortune if Westlaw didn't give us teachers free access. But Westlaw lets me access this service for free only because the marginal costs of my use of it are comparatively low. If they had to print and mail the results of my queries every day -- which would cost them a lot in labor and postage -- they'd almost certainly not make the service available free, even to law schools. Likewise, Minnesota gubernatorial and senatorial candidates recently debated one another online, using an Internet mailing list.<73> A moderator asked a question; the candidates gave their answers, in a few paragraphs each; and they then responded to one another. There was a message or two a day from each candidate. I suspect most of the "viewers" read the messages online, but many could easily have configured their mail systems to automatically print the messages, if that's what they preferred.<74> The debate didn't change the course of the election -- there were only 500 people watching -- but it did show the power of electronic communications. Once the candidates agreed to participate, there was no need to persuade the media that carrying the debate would attract enough viewers or readers. Similarly, Patrick Crispen, a public-spirited student at the University of Alabama, recently ran a series of online Internet tutorials.<75> Crispen's announcement of his tutorials generated 62,000 subscribers.<76> Obviously, the number would have been different had the tutorials not been free, and because of current Internet etiquette, he would have had a harder time advertising the service. Still, Crispen has, with no expenditure other than of his time -- and of his university's computer resources, though I doubt he put too much of a strain on them, especially since the messages could have been routed during off-peak hours -- gotten an audience many newspapers would envy.<77> Finally, when reporters at the San Francisco Chronicle and the San Francisco Examiner went on strike in November 1994, the striking employees -- unfazed by lack of the newspapers' printing plant and distribution network -- produced their own paper, the San Francisco Free Press, and delivered it over the Internet. And the electronic newspaper was in fact the first to break a story, which got a lot of play during the November 1994 senatorial campaign, about Senator Dianne Feinstein's alleged employment of an illegal alien.<78> b. Custom-Tailored Magazines and Newspapers But beyond increasing the number of publications, ebooks will also change the very concept of reading a magazine or a newspaper. No one wants to read, say, the whole {L.A. Times,} with all its stories about news, features, sports, entertainment, food, travel, cars, and so on. No one reads the newspaper cover to cover. They read most parts of some sections and some parts of others, and throw out the rest. What people want are newspapers and magazines with stories about the things that interest {them} (just as they want radio with the songs they like). They may want a newspaper which has, say, the top twenty international stories of the day (with a special focus on news from Africa), the top five national stories, the top five science stories, the top ten law stories, news about football and about the Los Angeles Dodgers, and, say, ten random stories just for the unexpected surprise. Readers do want the stories to be professionally investigated, written, and selected, perhaps by the same staff that brings them the newspaper or the magazine today. But they want them in the mix they prefer. And newspapers already realize people want this -- witness the local editions of various papers, such as the San Fernando Valley edition of the {L.A. Times}. Today's newspapers and magazines are creatures of a particular economic fact of the print age: To print cheaply and distribute cheaply, you have to print many copies of exactly the same thing. If most readers in Los Angeles don't care about science or about Angola, the paper puts in few stories about these subjects, and the oddball readers lose out. On the other hand, the front page is covered with O. J. Simpson stories, and the handful of non-O.J.- trial-buffs must wade through them to get to what they like. But electronic distribution doesn't require uniformity. It's a trivial software problem to let a user configure his own mix of materials, and to assemble and index them for him. Subscribers will set up this mix at subscription time; people who don't want to bother with this will get a default mix, but will be able to change it whenever they like. Moreover, there's no reason the subscribers wouldn't be able to mix stories from different stories -- local news, for instance, from the {L.A. Times,} international news from the {New York Times,} and national and business news from both the {New York Times} and {Wall Street Journal,} to get two different perspectives. 5. Dealing with Information Overload {Opinion Articles:} With opinion articles as with music, there'll soon be many more options than most consumers will know how to deal with. There's something valuable -- as well as limiting -- in the fact that your daily paper gives you, say, four op-ed pieces rather than forty thousand. But as I mentioned in the music discussion, information overload is not a new phenomenon. There are far more books than any consumer can personally browse, and yet we're quite happy with this, and don't clamor for less selection. We generally prefer to go to bigger bookstores rather than smaller ones, even though smaller ones will have done some extra preselection for us. True, we partly rely on the screening done by publishers, who'll at least have rejected the total garbage, but we also rely on reviewers, on word-of-mouth, on our familiarity with particular writers and artists, on the possibility of browsing, and on advertising. These mechanisms will still exist for the new media, even if publisher selection doesn't. People will still read reviews, and hear about good items from friends. People will also be familiar with existing popular columnists, and with existing organizations that are starting newsletters. Moreover, electronic distribution can make possible new selection devices. One particularly useful new service -- similar to the custom-mix radio I mentioned above -- would be a subscription that delivers a different column every day, perhaps selected by general topic or by political perspective. Thus, together with my daily William F. Buckley, Libertarian Report, and Column Left/Column Right on the First Amendment, I could also get a different center-to-right-wing column every day, and twice a week random (but well-regarded) columns from all sides of the spectrum. When I find a column I really like, I might subscribe to it, or perhaps order a few more days' worth to see if I really like it. And the service could be even cheaper than normal subscriptions, because the columnists would probably be willing to waive their royalties in order to get the exposure the service would provide. It might be cheaper still, or free but for the cost of paper, if the service takes advertising, or takes money from the columnists in exchange for reprinting the columns. This latter approach will create a potential conflict of interest, as well as a barrier for poor columnists (though not a very high one); but there'll probably be both free and pay services, with the pay services touting their independence, much as {Consumer Reports} and {Ms.} magazine, which don't accept advertising, do today.<79> {Books:} In the book market, reviewers will play an even more critical role than they do today. Moreover, as with music, their recommendations will have more influence because they'll be easily available when the customer is buying the book. Electronic bookstores will let customers select only those books that were professionally reviewed, or books reviewed by particular reviewers (or reviewing corporations) -- for instance, "new Science Fiction books which got positive reviews from reviewer X, Y, or Z." A writer would, instead of sending his manuscript to a publisher, send it to several reviewing services specializing in his field. Most reviewing services probably wouldn't write full-length reviews; instead, they'd give the book some sort of grade, and maybe a one-paragraph summary and critique for the good ones. They might in particular compare it to books by well-established authors (e.g., "people who like Larry McMurtry would probably like this one"). The services might charge the author for their efforts. Rates would start at a minimum which compensates for the reviewing employee's time -- perhaps as little as a few hundred dollars -- and would rise as the service becomes more and more popular and can thus charge extra for its name. In a sense this will reinvent part of today's publishing business, and lead to some of the costs associated with it. Publishers perform an important screening function, which will still have to be performed. Publishers also perform an important editing function, and there may well be editing services or freelance editors, who'll ask for either a fee or a royalty (which may not be possible for books that seem unlikely to succeed). Thus, there'll still be organizations with the power to sink a book -- here, reviewers rather than publishers -- and there'll still be up-front costs -- reviewing and editing fees rather than printing costs. But the costs will be much lower, and the reviewers will be more diverse, will represent more tastes, and will be better able to serve niche markets. C. Video (TV and Movies) "[T]hough the perceived defects of [television] are many, . . . they can be more or less subsumed in two words: {vast wasteland}."<80> Newton Minow, then chairman of the FCC, coined this pejorative in 1961, and it has (justly) stuck. But if your local bookstore let you buy, at any given hour, only five books -- each chosen for maximum appeal to 250 million people -- you'd think of publishing as a vast wasteland, too. This would remain true even if the store had fifty books, or maybe even 500 books to match the touted 500-channel cable system of the future. There'd be more chance that you'd get what you want,<81> but still you'd often be dissatisfied.<82> The problem with TV isn't lack of material. There's been lots of excellent television created in the medium's almost 50 years. Add to that the many great movies that have been made, and there's enough for each of us to be able to watch for hours every day and still only get the stuff we enjoy. The problem is that broadcasting can't get you what you want when you want it. It can only get you what millions of people prefer,<83> and it can only give it to you at the time chosen by the broadcaster, not the time chosen by you. Five hundred channels may help, because they may make room for material that appeals to only, say, a few hundred thousand people; but that will still be inadequate.<84> What people would like, I believe, is to choose from home -- at any time convenient to them -- any TV show or movie they want, just as they can choose a book in a bookstore, only more conveniently and less expensively (or even free; the medium might still be advertiser-supported).<85> Some people might still want someone else to decide; they might, for instance, ask for a random comedy, or a random comedy praised by a given reviewer. They might even ask for the latest episode of a particular new show, just as they do on TV today, though at the time that's convenient for them. But they'll be the ones who choose, or choose to leave the choice to someone else. This, of course, is "video-on-demand," which is already being tested -- in a primitive form -- in various markets.<86> Many current video-on-demand proposals have gotten a skeptical market response. But the barriers all seem to me to be a function of current technology -- the degree to which today's homes are properly wired (or fibered) for this service, the current costs of the equipment, and so on. The question, I think, is only whether video-on-demand will start arriving now or in several years. {Effect on What Will Be Available:} As with the other media, this customization will give people access to much more diverse material. Today, to be broadcast on TV, new programs must have an expected audience of millions. To justify access to the scarce shelf space available in video stores, videotapes also need a large market. Lots of good stuff that doesn't appeal to a large enough audience never makes its way to the TV stations or video stores. The new system should also increase the amount of new material being made. The cost of producing high-quality, high-production- values entertainment -- from $500,000 to over $1 million per hour<87> -- will slow down this diversification. So long as production costs remain high, each new program will still have to appeal to a lot of people.<88> Still, it will probably need less of an audience than it does today, when producers face both high production costs and limited distribution channels. Moreover, some video programming -- talk shows, talking heads shows such as the {McLaughlin Group,} stand-up comedy, and some kinds of sporting events -- costs comparatively little to produce.<89> Production of these shows ought to mushroom. II. Social Consequences A. Democratization and Diversification The new technologies I outlined above will, I believe, both democratize the information marketplace -- make it more accessible to comparatively poor speakers as well as the rich ones -- and diversify it. Of course, the power to make one's speech globally available isn't the power to make it globally heard. One still has to get people to listen, either through advertising or word-of- mouth or good reviews or other devices. Advertising will still cost money, and well-funded bands or columnists or newsletters will attract more readers than poorer ones will. Nonetheless, while advertising is obviously useful, it's not strictly necessary; many products are sold today in large part through word-of-mouth or reviews (especially when one considers radio as the reviewing medium that it is). Wealth will certainly remain relevant in the new information structure, but it will be a good deal less relevant than it is today. Likewise, a greater diversity of available speech need not lead to diversification of what is actually consumed. It's possible that after the infobahn comes up, most people will still consume largely what they do today. But at least those people whose tastes differ from the majority's will be served. They might, of course, continue to complain about the majority's bad taste; but that's something no technology can do much about. B. Shift of Control from the Intermediaries and What It Will Mean The trends I've pointed to have one thing in common: They tend to shift control from intermediaries -- record labels, radio and TV station owners, newspaper, magazine, and book publishers -- to speakers and listeners. The relatively low cost of electronic distribution gives more control over what is said to speakers: A speaker need no longer satisfy the intermediaries before being allowed to speak. The relatively low cost of {personalized} electronic distribution gives more control over what is heard to listeners; a listener may select his own mix of music and information, rather than taking what the intermediaries give him. 1. Shift of Control to Listeners {Ease of Getting More Information:} The shift of control to listeners will, I think, make people better informed about the things in which they're interested. Say I want to read science stories, news about Eastern Europe, and opinions about the crime problem. The newspaper today gives me only as many stories on these topics as a typical reader might want to see. But I want more! With the new technology, I'll be able to get as many of these stories as I want, either through short newsletters (which will be cheap and easy to subscribe to), or through configuring for myself the mix of the stories in my morning paper. I may even be able to get important source material, such as the complete text of a speech, or a document, or an interview. Such material rarely gets printed in its entirety, because space and the patience of most readers are limited. But it can easily be made available electronically to those who want it.<90> {Ease of Being Closed-Minded:} On the other hand, part of the value of the mass media is that they expose readers to topics and viewpoints they {didn't} select. A reader who thinks he doesn't care about science might come across a science story on the front page and find it interesting. A liberal reader might stumble across a conservative column in his daily paper and be persuaded by it. But both these stories might not have been ones the reader would have subscribed to had he had the choice. Of course, with the new system, people who want a variety of topics or views will be able to easily get them. Wise readers will probably request some general news for their mix, rather than just saying "give me international news, law, and science, and nothing else. Conservatives could subscribe to well-regarded liberals, and vice versa. Some columnists will team up with others to produce two-sides-of-the-issue columns, much like the Column Left and Column Right in some newspapers today, or the TV show {Cross- fire}. There may well be more multi-sided presentations available under the new system than there are today (just because there'll generally be more options). Many people, though, might not want a variety of topics, and especially a variety of views. Most of us to some extent prefer to listen to people with whom we agree. Often we won't even read opposing views in a newspaper that we've already bought; and we're especially unlikely to pay money -- even small sums -- for opinions with which we know we disagree.<91> Every reader, of course, has a right to be closed-minded; and people are already plenty closed-minded today, so the new technologies might not make a major difference in this. But they may at least marginally increase the degree to which people shield themselves from topics and opinions they think they dislike. {Common Culture:} Another part of the value of the mass media is that they give viewers a shared base of information. Every evening millions of people watch network news; every week they watch more or less the same TV shows. When they talk about events with friends or coworkers, they at least have a starting point for discussion. But as the sources of information and entertainment become less generic and more custom-tailored, people may lose some of this common ground. They may find themselves having fewer shared cultural referents, and less common knowledge about current events, even if they have more knowledge about the events that interest them most.<92> People who read the Democratic Party's organ and people who read the Libertarian Party's organ might have a hard time even speaking the same language about the issues. Again, those who want to share common ground with their peers may choose to continue listening to Top-40, or watch news shows that aim for a well-rounded, mainstream view of the world. But many people won't do this. It's hardly likely that American society will fall apart because of this, but it's at least possible that more diversity of sources might mean less common ground and less social cohesion.<93> 2. Shift of Control to Speakers The Decline of Private Speech Regulations While American government agencies generally don't regulate speech, private parties do. Publishers sometimes refuse to publish material they disagree with. Private groups sometimes pressure publishers to drop certain material. And even the viewpoint- neutral reluctance of publishers to accept work that appeals to too few consumers has the effect of shutting out political fringe groups on all sides of the spectrum. The shift of control from publishers to speakers will greatly weaken these private speech regulations. When speech comes straight from the speaker to the listener, there's no one in between to regulate the speech, and no one for various groups to pressure if they think the speech is reprehensible. Threats of boycotts may work against diversified companies, which sell information to many markets; someone can tell, say, Time Warner Records "If you carry Ice-T's {Cop Killer,} I won't buy other Time Warner material." But telling Ice-T "If you keep singing {Cop Killer,} I won't buy your other material" probably won't work -- Ice-T knows that people who say this probably wouldn't buy his music anyway. There's no consensus today about whether such private regulations are proper. Some consider them almost as dangerous as government censorship; others argue that private pressure on speakers is legitimate and sometimes even laudable.<94> But regardless of one's normative judgment on this, the new information media will make it much harder for such private speech regulation, good or bad, to take place. Of course, there'll still be some intermediaries. Though the power of publishers will wane, the equivalents of the music stores and bookstores -- the music databases, and the computer systems that people access to subscribe to opinion columns, to buy books, or to get video-on-demand -- will remain. They could refuse to carry certain kinds of speech, and various groups could pressure them into doing this. But such a refusal will probably have a limited effect on the speech that's being rejected. Each infobahn-connected home will be able to access every computer service in the nation. If one service refuses to carry, say, gangsta rap music, others can instantly take advantage of the resulting market. And starting a new nationwide electronic service should be comparatively cheap, certainly cheaper than starting a nationwide chain of bookstores or music stores. Today, it's conceivable that all the major stores in an area might refuse to carry a certain product. But even if all the mainstream computer services reject a particular genre, other services -- say, an all-gangsta-rap service, or even a service specializing in materials that others don't carry -- could easily spring up. The private speech regulations will remain only where there must be intermediaries who select what gets distributed, for instance in newspapers, whose editors will still control who writes for them.<95> Another form of speech regulation I alluded to above -- regulation by poverty and unpopularity -- will also become much less potent. Many extremist groups have relatively little ability to speak out because they don't have enough of a base to fund their speech. At least some KKK chapters, for instance, are dormant largely because they're broke.<96> Cheap electronic distribution might mean that not only the ACLU or NRA newsletters, but also the KKK and Communist Party newsletters, can be sent to millions of subscribers.<97> One would hope these fringe groups will find few people willing to listen, but their voices will be amplified along with the voices of worthier organizations. Finally, the new media might affect one more sort of speech regulation: self-regulation for accuracy. It's generally assumed that intermediaries -- publishers, editors, and broadcasters -- help make sure the things we read and hear are actually true. They might, for instance, fact-check articles, or refuse to work with writers who are known to be unreliable. But when speakers can communicate to the public directly, it's possible their speech will be less trustworthy: They might not be willing to hire fact-checkers, or might not be influenced enough by professional journalistic norms, or might not care enough about their long-term reputation for accuracy. Talk radio, for instance, has been criticized for being unreliable in large part because of how democratic and spontaneous it is.<98> It's not clear, though, what the magnitude of this would be. The new technologies will give some untrustworthy speakers a forum that responsible editors would deny them, and some people will end up misinformed by these speakers. But the majority of new speakers may be no worse than most media of today. Many leading publishers actually don't employ fact-checkers;<99> and while today's media aren't notorious for intentional falsehoods, misunderstandings and misreporting seem quite common -- consider how often we all find errors in newspaper articles about subjects we know well. At worst, the new technologies may supplement some fairly unreliable publications with other, perhaps more unreliable, ones. At best, they might allow the publication of more trustworthy materials -- for instance, science news publications put out by specialists, rather than generalist journalists -- that couldn't be printed before. C. Poor Consumers When I say the new technologies will shift power to listeners, I mean of course listeners who can afford the new technologies. But what about consumers who can't buy a computer, a digital recorder, a printer, an ebook, and an infobahn hookup? {Music:} Poor consumers should be benefited by electronic music delivery. Even if they can't afford the hardware, they should be able to buy their music from public vending machines.<100> While it may cost more to buy from these machines than it would to buy from home, it should still cost less than it does now. Of course consumers will still need devices that play these recordings, but there's no reason to think they'll end up costing more than about what CD players do now. {Short Opinion Articles:} Opinion articles may be different. Home delivery of selected opinion articles will work because subscribing to the articles and getting them each morning is easy. If your favorite columns are there on your printer when you wake up, you'll read them. But if to get them you must go every day (or even every week) to a public terminal, select what you want, and wait for it to print, the result will be much less useful to you. And the cost of such public access may be a good deal higher as a proportion of the normal price than it would be for music. On the other hand, this system might not be much worse for poor people than the existing one. People who can't afford the needed computer hardware might also be unable to afford a $200 yearly subscription to the {Los Angeles Times}. And with over 80% of all U. S. households owning VCRs,<101> the affordability of home electronics to even the not-so-rich shouldn't be underestimated. {Books, Magazines, and Newspapers:} Books, magazines, and newspapers are a still different matter. It's easy to imagine public terminals that download such materials -- especially books and magazines -- onto your ebook.<102> They won't be any harder to use than a bookstore is today, and the work itself will be cheaper than it is in a bookstore. However, the ebook itself may be a sizable up-front investment; and it may be particularly hard to afford for parents of small children, because the children may be likely to break it or lose it. The new technology may also require a rethinking of a substantial subsidy the government now provides for readers: public libraries. Even if electronically distributed books cost much less than books do today, many people would still prefer to borrow the books for free. How would libraries be able to lend electronically distributed books? Under the model I described above, a "book" will no longer be a tangible item, not even, say, a floppy disk. To buy a book, you'd just download it onto your ebook. If a library, though, downloads the book for you, you haven't borrowed the book -- you've gotten it permanently, a clear copyright violation. But even if a library tries to better emulate the economic effects of conventional library lending -- embeds a three-week expiration date in the electronic data,<103> and refuses to lend the same book to more than one customer at a time -- this would still violate copyright. Copying electronic data onto a computer, even in a way that has the same market effect as lending of paper books by today's libraries, is a copy and almost certainly an infringement.<104> While Congress can change this scheme, copyright owners may lobby hard against it. They already look with envy at some other countries' copyright laws, which provide for a royalty to be paid every time a book is lent.<105> On the other hand, the new technology may greatly decrease many of the costs of running libraries -- shelf space, reshelving, and so on. Some accommodation might be reached in which authors' organizations might agree to some blanket licensing agreement,<106> or to changes in the copyright law; the money saved by libraries on paper books could be spent to compensate authors on a per-loan basis.<107> Used book stores, another device through which people today can get books cheaply, will also run into problems in the ebook age. It's not copyright infringement to resell a paper book,<108> but it almost certainly would be infringement to copy a book from your ebook disk to someone else's, even if you delete the original.<109> Changing the law to allow copy-and-delete transactions -- on the theory that they are just like selling a tangible copy -- may be unfair to authors. Used book sales today have a limited effect on new book sales, because used books are less desirable than new books (they're often worn and torn), and because used bookstores often don't have large or well-arranged stocks. But if used electronic books could be sold, they could substantially undercut sales of new books: Used electronic books are as good as new ones; national electronic used bookstores could have huge selection; and obviously they wouldn't need a lot of clerks to keep the books in sorted order. Authors could legitimately complain that allowing sales of used electronic books will cost them much more than allowing sales of used paper books does today.<110> AW legislative or contractual compromise could be reached -- for instance, a royalty could be imposed on each resale of a used electronic book -- but it might be not easy. {Video-on-Demand}: Finally, video-on-demand probably will not, once it's a mature technology, be particularly burdensome even for relatively poor people. While it might require new TV equipment, and again the infobahn connection, there's no reason to think it will eventually cost much more than a TV, a VCR, and a telephone -- staples of American homes -- do today. This is especially true because video-on-demand is as good an advertising medium as commercial TV is. D. What Will Happen to Advertising (Both Commercial and Political) The new technologies will have at least three significant effects on advertising: First, it will be easier and cheaper to have advertising-less media. Consumers generally don't much like commercials on radio and TV, because (unlike in newspapers) the ads interrupt the program content. Some consumers dislike commercials enough that they'd be willing to pay extra for advertising-less media, as they now do for some cable movie channels. Other consumers would prefer to have free (or cheaper) entertainment, and would be willing to sit through the commercials to get it. Still, as the costs of providing services -- such as custom-mix cable radio -- fall, the amount of advertising on free services will fall, too, as services compete with one another based on how few commercials they have.<111> Advertisements in newspapers and magazines are less intrusive, so there'll be less pressure to reduce their quantity. Some publications might refuse ads to prove their independence from outside pressure,<112> but this seems unlikely to become common. Second, newspapers will lose a vast amount of classified ad revenue. This revenue accounted for 40% of total newspaper ad revenue in the late 1980s,<113> and some project it will reach 60% by 2000.<114> But paper classifieds are far inferior, for both buyers and sellers, to electronic classifieds that are untied to any newspaper. A database of, say, all apartments for rent in the city would be much easier to search through than a newspaper classified section: The renter could, for instance (from a public-access terminal<115>), ask for an instant list of all the 1-bedroom apartments for less than $850 per month within 3 miles of UCLA, perhaps plus apartments that are a bit cheaper but a bit further, or more expensive but closer.<116> The list should be more complete, because the information will be easier and cheaper to post. And the list should be timelier -- the information will become available as soon as the landlord posts it, and can be removed as soon as the apartment is rented. Electronic classifieds are better on all counts than paper ones, and newspapers will have to adjust to a huge revenue loss when the paper classifieds stop coming in.<117> The loss of classified revenues, coupled with the cost savings and opportunities for extra profits from electronic distribution, should help push newspaper publishers into going electronic. Third, individualization of the media will let advertisers target customers better than ever before. Instead of one newspaper with ads aimed at several hundred thousand people, each electronically delivered newspaper will have ads calculated to fit the particular subscriber's profile -- age, sex, and whatever other information the newspaper gets at subscription time, or can deduce from the mix of stories he's ordered.<118> The same would be true for the other media. The greater ease of targeting ads may also change the way political campaigns reach voters. This is already happening: In one political consultant's words, "if you want to talk to women, buy `Sisters' Saturday night; men, you buy ESPN; seniors, `Murder She Wrote'; everyone, [the local football team] or `60 Minutes.'"<119> Another consultant points out that "working mothers . . . don't watch TV regularly, but do sit in traffic jams -- which makes radio a good buy."<120> When targeting becomes even easier, candidates can speak even more directly to particular voters, with ads specially targeted at those people. This would give voters more communications about the issues that matter to them; and voters who'd want deeper treatment of the issues might get their wish, as campaigns try to avoid alienating them with shallower commercials. On the other hand, targeted ads might in some ways be worse for the democratic process than mass ads are. The targeted ads might appeal more to parochial interests and prejudices and less to the common good; and candidates might be able to make arguments to small groups that they'd rather not make to the public at large.<121> These are, of course, only tentative guesses; still, it seems likely that the demassification<122> of the mass media will substantially change the way both products and politicians are advertised. To the extent advertising is important to political campaigns, these changes ought to be considered. III. A Few Words about the New Media and the First Amendment A. Existing Flashpoints The proto-infobahn of today -- the Internet, bulletin boards, and various commercial services -- has already generated quite a few First Amendment controversies. Professor Branscomb has ably summarized many of them in another article in this Symposium.<123> Some of these may only be transplants of conventional questions into a new but essentially similar environment. For instance, there's already a lively debate about the propriety of regulating sexually harassing speech;<124> harassing speech on electronic bulletin boards might just be a special case of this. The mens rea requirements imposed by the Supreme Court on libel actions may be adequate for protecting bulletin board operators from liability for messages whose contents they had no way of knowing. <125> Likewise, the advent of electronic communications may change how child pornography is distributed,<126> but I don't see how it would change the rules relating to child pornography. Other such conflicts, though, may well require at least some changes to existing doctrine, because they reflect ways in which the new media genuinely differ from the old. The law of speech is premised on certain (often unspoken) assumptions about the way the speech market operates. If these assumptions aren't valid for the new technologies, the law may have to evolve to reflect the changes. Newspapers, for instance, are today held strictly liable for copyright infringement;<127> part of the reason for this is that they have broad control over what they choose to print.<128> When this assumption of control fails, as it does for electronic bulletin boards, strict liability may be inappropriate and perhaps even unconstitutional.<129> The courts that developed this rule might not have consciously thought about this assumption, and it's certainly unlikely that they thought about it in a First Amendment context.<130> But it seems to me that in a world where this assumption was false, courts could well have developed -- and could still develop -- a different rule. Likewise, as the economic constraints on sending tidal waves of unsolicited mail are removed, legal restrictions may have to take their place. Today such restrictions might be seen as unconstitutional, at least as to noncommercial speech.<131> But if indeed e-mailing is next to free, the "short, though regular, journey from mail box to trash can" may cease to be "an acceptable burden, at least so far as the Constitution is concerned."<132> Similarly, in the obscenity context the "community standards" test presumes sellers know which community they are selling to. As computer networks make it possible for people to get obscenity without so much as supplying a mailing address, the very concept of local community standards may become obsolete.<133> Still, all these seem like small changes, ones that don't cast into doubt the basic rules of the First Amendment: the general requirement of content-neutrality, the exemption of certain kinds of speech from protection, the lower protection given to commercial speech, and so on.<134> But if the discussion in Parts I and II is correct, the new technologies will change the speech market much more dramatically than we've seen so far. Today's First Amendment law evolved in a media world which had particular characteristics. Most of the speech that mattered was carried by a relatively few established outlets. Extremist speakers had fairly little access to the public. The main news sources -- TV programs and newspapers -- provided a mix of ostensibly nonpartisan information about a variety of topics. The limited set of sources gave people a more or less common base of information to argue from. These underlying characteristics are, in my view, more significant than the ones discussed in the last few paragraphs. If they change, what consequences will this have for First Amendment law? B. A Rosy Future Let me begin my answer with the good news. Existing First Amendment doctrine is founded on some rather idealized premises. "[T]he best test of truth is the power of the thought to get itself accepted in the competition of the market."<135> "[T]he fitting remedy for evil counsels is good ones."<136> People who are offended by speech may "effectively avoid further bombardment of their sensibilities simply by averting their eyes."<137> These premises may often be true, but sometimes they simply aren't. Sometimes the supporters of a thought have millions of dollars, while opponents are too poor to effectively compete. Some markets are monopolized by one speaker, for instance a single cable system.<138> Good counsels from poor speakers may often not be an adequate remedy for evil ones from richer, louder speakers.<139> And Justice Stevens had a point: "[S]ay[ing] that one may avoid further offense by turning off the radio . . . is like saying that the remedy for an assault is to run away after the first blow."<140> Unless offense is simply constitutionally irrelevant (in which case the possibility of averting one's eyes or ears shouldn't matter), once the words are heard the injury is complete. The Court has heard these arguments. It has accepted that they may sometimes be valid. And yet it has generally -- most notably in {Turner Broadcasting v. FCC} and {Miami Herald v. Tornillo} -- refused to change the doctrine to accommodate them.<141> It may have been right to refuse; it might, for instance, be too dangerous to let the government intervene when it thinks it's found "market failure,"<142> or an inability to counterspeak, or a situation where the sting of offensive words is so great that averting one's eyes is no remedy. And even when the Court's assumptions are counterfactual, they might still be required because they represent "the theory of our Constitution"<143> -- a basic principle which government must assume to be true even when it might not be. But it remains true that the Court has based its jurisprudence on an idealized view of the world, a view that doesn't quite correspond to the world in which we live. What I've tried to suggest above is that this idealized world -- where money is no barrier to speaking; where it's easy to avert eyes from offensive speech; where there's more than one newspaper in each town, and something other than a vast wasteland on TV -- is much closer to the electronic media world of the future than it is to the print and broadcast media world of the present. If my predictions are right, the new technologies will make it much easier for all ideas, whether backed by the rich or the poor, to participate in the marketplace. Even if many individuals still can't afford to counterspeak effectively, there'll be many more organizations able to speak out on all sides of an issue. And when one's radio is no longer a dumb receiver but rather a computer capable of screening out whatever the listener wants removed, a householder really will be able to "avert his eyes" -- and his children's eyes -- from radio profanity (or TV nudity or what have you), rather than having to wait for the first blow.<144> Copyright specialists are fond of suggesting that we operate in an electronic age under a copyright law created for a print age. It seems to me that during the print age, the Supreme Court created a First Amendment for the electronic age. The fictions the Court found necessary to embrace are turning, at least in part, into fact. C. A Possible Dark Side But some of the other assumptions that the new technologies will upset may lead to more trouble. {Missouri Knights of the KKK v. Kansas City}<145> might be something of a cautionary tale. In exchange for giving a franchise to a cable company, Kansas City demanded that the company provide a public-access channel. Everything went well until the Ku Klux Klan decided to put on its own show, which offended the city government so much that authorized the cable system to shut the entire channel down. The city's action was ultimately overturned on First Amendment grounds, but the story shows what can happen when the assumptions underlying certain rules are changed. The city's willingness to provide a forum for the little guy, it turned out, was based (perhaps unconsciously) on the supposition that the little guys would either provide a public service or at worst be harmless eccentrics. When the assumption proved false, the consensus behind the rule evaporated. As the new media arrive, they may likewise cause some popular sentiment for changes in the doctrine. Today, for instance, the First Amendment rules that give broad protection to extremist speakers -- Klansmen, Communists, and the like -- are relatively low-cost, because these groups are politically rather insignificant. Even without government regulation, they are in large measure silenced by lack of funds and by the disapproval of the media establishment.<146> What will happen when the KKK becomes able to conveniently send its views to hundreds of thousands of supporters throughout the country, or create its own TV show that can be ordered from any infobahn-connected household?<147> Likewise, the broad protection for false speech<148> evolved in a time when the main suppliers of news and opinion were large, ostensibly nonpartisan, media organizations. Obviously these broadcasters and publishers weren't entirely reliable -- they still lose some libel lawsuits even after {New York Times v. Sullivan} -- but they were the sort of media that people can feel relatively comfortable with. But with the emergence of talk radio as a powerful force, some have begun to grouse. Consider, for instance, a recent speech to the National Association of Broadcasters by FCC Chairman Reed Hundt, whose Commission decides whether to renew the broadcasters' licenses. Chairman Hundt, focusing specifically on talk radio, "urged station owners and management to . . . emphasiz[e] accuracy and truth over a quest for ratings and advertising dollars."<149> "`As a society,'" the chairman said, "`we need solutions to public disinformation and misinformation, but solutions that don't involve governmental intrusion and yet don't leave us callously indifferent to truth or falsity.'"<150> While this isn't yet a call for greater regulation -- the chairman specifically "stressed that the FCC should not be the judge of content or quality in radio's public discourses"<151> -- it shows the sort of concern that may be a harbinger of future regulatory proposals. Finally, current First Amendment law developed in a time when the public got its news and opinion from sources that provided a fairly broad mix of topics and viewpoints. Someone buying a newspaper or watching the nightly news would see a variety of stories, stories that professional editors thought fairly covered the most important issues facing the nation. And these stories would be a common base that people would be able to talk about with their acquaintances. The media, of course, were often criticized for falling down on the job, by covering fluff instead of the really important issues.<152> But these criticisms only help show that people do think it's the media's job to give the public a trustworthy mix of the truly important news of the day. As listeners get more control over the topics and viewpoints they see,<153> they may choose to focus on a much narrower mix of information. They may subscribe only to articles on topics in which they're interested, or to commentators with whose opinions they already agree. They may consciously choose fluff -- more easily than they can today -- exclude the serious news.<154> Listeners will no longer be a captive audience to the selection the intermediaries -- publishers and broadcasters -- want to feed them. Will listeners do a better job of informing themselves than the intermediaries have been doing? I think the answer is yes, but others -- including many in the audience when I presented this paper at the Symposium -- disagree. And when the media aren't there to help set a national agenda, or to give people a common base of information to argue from, will people be able to deliberate together? In my view, none of these changes, significant as they may be, should cause us to reconsider the basics of First Amendment law. The dangers of extremists with access to the media, or of falsehoods with an audience in the millions, or of an ill-informed electorate are quite real; but the dangers of content regulation, it seems to me, are greater. And these dangers are, of course, exacerbated by the difficulty of doing anything about the most significant problems -- the possibility that people will choose to watch or read infotainment instead of the important news of the day seems especially intractable. Professor Powe's criticism of the FCC's attempts at content regulation seems to me to be hard to answer.<155> Still, the media will change. My thesis throughout the paper has been that they'll change dramatically. As people will find themselves in a new media environment there will be new calls for regulation, and new calls for changes to First Amendment doctrines that some people may think are no longer apt. I may be wrong in my predictions about what the new media order will look like. But the one thing that seems certain is that the new order will, in many ways, be vastly different from the old. * Acting Professor, UCLA Law School (volokh@law.ucla.edu). J.D., UCLA, 1992. B.S., Math-Computer Science, UCLA, 1983. My thanks to Akhil Amar, Laura Brodbeck, Eugenia Gershman, Neal Katyal, Judge Alex Kozinski, Dr. William Short, Gail Standish, and Alexander Volokh; and, of course, to my mother Anne and especially my father Vladimir, at whose knee I first learned about computers. 1. "[A]n unregulated marketplace of ideas will include `only those that are advocated by the rich, . . . those who can borrow from others, or . . . those who can put together a product that will attract sufficient advertisers or subscribers to sustain the enterprise." Owen Fiss, {Free Speech and Social Structure}, 71 Iowa L. Rev. 1405, 1413 (1986). "A comparatively few private hands are in a position to determine not only the content of information, but its very availability." Jerome A. Barron, {Access to the Press -- A New First Amendment Right}, 80 Harv. L. Rev. 1641, 1643 (1967). "Freedom of the press is guaranteed only to those who own one." A.J. Liebling, The Press 32 (1975). See also Cass R. Sunstein, Democracy and the Problem of Free Speech 17-18, 57-58 (1993). 2. See, e.g., Fiss, {supra} note 1; Sunstein, {supra} note 1, at 107-14. 3. The information superhighway is supposed to provide cheap, extremely high-speed communications to pretty much the whole country. Functionally, it should operate like the phone system, but because it will use fiber-optics instead of wires, it should be able to transmit data much more quickly than phone lines can. 4. The word -- in my view, a much snappier synonym for information superhighway -- was apparently invented by Lynn Levine, director of market research and data sales at Warren Publishing, in 1993. E-mail from Brock Meeks to author, Oct. 27, 1994 and Nov. 6, 1994 (copy of message remarking on this date-stamped Oct. 21, 1993); telephone conversation with Lynn Levine, Nov. 7, 1994. The word's first appearance in NEXIS-searchable publications was on February 28, 1994; during the rest of 1994, there have been over 700 references to it in those publications. 5. Larry Lessig, ___ Yale L.J. ___ (forthcoming 1995). 6. Sidney Shemel & M. William Krasilovsky, This Business of Music 4-5 (6th ed. 1990). Artists get 7% to 13% nominal royalties (less for new artists, more for the superstars), usually minus a 10% deduction -- ostensibly, but not actually, to cover unsold records -- and another 10% to 25% deduction for packaging. {Id.} 7. Consumer convenience is especially valuable for music, which is often bought on impulse. If someone hears a song on the radio and wants to buy the album, the copyright owner would prefer that the listener be able to buy it immediately, or at least as soon as possible. If the listener won't go to a record store for another week or month, the song might by then be entirely forgotten. 8. The computer system will probably have some built-in check to make sure you're not using the preplay service too often, as a substitute for buying the album. 9. David Rohde, {Major Record Labels Try to Copy the Success of Independents}, Christian Science Monitor, Sept. 23, 1994, at 11 (noting that Nirvana's first album, {Bleach}, was recorded for $800); Michael Snyder, {Urban Folk-Rockers Swell Up}, S.F. Chronicle, Apr. 17, 1994, at 35 (describing an album that was made for $900, and was picked up by a major label which rereleased it with no alterations). 10. {See supra} note 6. 11. {Cf.} Michael L. Evans, {Role Reversal: Users Will Dictate the Development of Tomorrow's Real Estate}, Nat'l Real Estate Investor, Sept. 1994, at EY3 (describing IBM and Blockbuster Entertainment's plan for on-demand inventory, where music and video will be delivered electronically to stores, which would then record it onto tangible media and not have to carry physical inventory); {infra} note 15 (describing how a mail-order CD facility can provide more titles because of lack of shelf space limitations and inventory costs). 12. Some music stores -- for instance, Borders Music and Blockbuster Music -- already let you pre-listen to albums; you take a CD, give it to the attendant, the attendant puts it into a CD player, and you sit there and listen to it. Still, it should be more convenient to pre-listen at home, where you don't have to deal with the attendant, wait in line if all the listening stations are busy, or spend forty minutes sitting in the music store to hear the whole album. 13. {Recording Industry Announces Midyear Growth}, PR Newswire, Aug. 11, 1994. 14. See Dan Hontz, {Let's Go Christmas Shopping; Mall- Hopping Easy with Your Computer}, Arizona Republic, Oct. 17, 1994, at E1. 15. {Cdconnection.com,} which lets you order CDs from your computer but delivers them to you through normal mail, boasts over 100,000 CDs, covering the entire catalogs of all U.S. major labels and more than 2000 independent labels, plus several thousand import CDs. I had looked for years for one album -- Leonard Cohen's {New Skin for the Old Ceremony} -- and finally found it there. 16. See Stephen Advokat, {Music for a Song?}, Chi. Trib., Oct. 11, 1993, at C1. {Cdconnection} sells a substantial fraction of its CDs at $8.50 to $10.50, a good deal less than what they cost at many stores, though it also charges a $3.50 flat fee for delivery (regardless of how many CDs you buy). According to {cdconnection}'s online promotional materials, the price savings are due to lack of inventory costs and to the service's ability to shop among various suppliers. 17. {Cdconnection} promises delivery times of 1 to 2 weeks to the western United States, and 2 to 3 weeks to the east. 18. See Computer Science & Telecomm. Board, Realizing the Information Future: The Internet and Beyond 30-38 (1994). 19. Storage of the music shouldn't be a problem, either. While the central databases will need a lot of storage, disk space today costs about 50 cents per megabyte, down from a bit under $2 per megabyte a year ago. Peter Baum, {High-Capacity Hard Drives}, MacUser, Oct. 1994, at 92. A 50-minute album today takes a bit less than 30 megabytes (taking advantage of compression), which translates into a one-time cost of $15 per album. {The Internet Multicasting Service}, Information Access, Feb. 18, 1994, at 10. 20. Note that the $5 will be for digital-quality music, while the $10 figure includes both tapes (which are cheaper but low- quality) and the more expensive digital CDs. People who insist on digital music may see the comparison as $5 for home delivery against $12 to $15 for CDs in stores. 21. Some people to whom I've described this theory have suggested that copyright owners won't license their music for electronic distribution because of fear of copyright infringement. Once music is electronically available, the argument goes, people could buy it once and then upload it to some computer bulletin board, or sell bootleg copies via e-mail. Copyright owners will therefore be reluctant to allow electronic music distribution. But while electronic copying is indeed a serious threat to music copyright owners, this threat will exist whether or not the music is available in some central database. Even without an electronic music database, a pirate could easily go to the store, buy a CD, and make many copies of it on his DCC or Minidisc recorder. The electronic databases might make commercial piracy more tempting, because it will increase the number of people with digital players, who are the pirates' potential customers. On the other hand, some of this effect may be counteracted by the lower costs of legitimate buying through the databases. Pirates will thrive more when their rip-offs are competing with $10 albums than with $5 albums. The music industry's reaction to DAT (Digital Audiotape) recorders, the first digital-quality home recording medium, is worth noting. When it became likely that home digital recording could let people easily make CD-quality copies of music, the music industry and the DAT industry agreed to a compromise, embodied in the Audio Home Recording Act of 1992, 17 U.S.C. 1001 {et seq.} The Act (1) legalized home noncommercial copying; (2) taxed DAT recorders and blank DATs, with the proceeds going to a fund to compensate copyright owners for the expected losses due to home copying; (3) required DAT recorder manufacturers to design their recorders in a way that limited the possibility of large-scale copying. A similar solution might be set up for the electronic music databases. The music industry may be able to push through a law that would compensate for possible copying losses by: (1) requiring an extra royalty payment on each electronic sale, and (2) requiring, say, designers of e-mail systems or bulletin board systems to put in checks that would make unauthorized copying harder. {Cf.} Working Group on Intellectual Property Rights, Intellectual Property and the National Information Infrastructure 125-30 (prelim. draft. July 1994) (suggesting restrictions on technology that helps pirates). This would hardly be a fool-proof solution, but it might provide some protection for copyright holders while still allowing them to exploit a powerful new sales tool. 22. Some music stores already have computerized music catalog machines (called Muzes), which let customers search through information on 80,000 albums and videotapes, by performer, by composer, or by album. The user makes his selections by touching the screen and, when a name is called for, typing on a keyboard. The interface is clear, and the display is full-color, with graphics. See Ken LaFave, {Muze System Takes Classical Music Lovers to Mount Olympus of CDs}, Phoenix Gazette, Apr. 26, 1994, at D3. 23. {Cdconnection.com}'s first Information screen asserts that its system contains 50,000 ratings from fellow customers, and 26,000 professional ratings from the All-Music Guide. You can look up the ratings easily as you browse through the CDs. 24. Some consumers might actually enjoy going to music stores, either because they like the atmosphere, or because they prefer being around other people rather than closeted at home, or because they like to go to music stores with friends. Movies, for instance, haven't been entirely supplanted by VCRs, in part because of the better picture and sound quality, but in part because people enjoy going to the movies. But even if one sees going to the music store as a pleasure rather than an inconvenience, there will probably be few people to whom it will be worth the extra cost. People can socialize with friends, or mingle with strangers, in lots of other places. If home access provides a better deal on music, most people will just buy the music at home and do their socializing at a restaurant or the beach. 25. Pauline Tam, {An On-line Link to Top Tunes Is Soon to Boom}, Vancouver Sun, Aug. 2, 1994, at C4. 26. Today such a transmission would take quite some time, because it goes over comparatively slow phone lines. {Id.} (3- to 4-minute song takes anywhere from 10 minutes to several hours to download). The whole point of the infobahn, though, is to change all that. Data can be sent much more quickly through fiber-optics than through wires; though no one is quite sure, people are generally expecting speeds tens of thousands of times greater than those of phone lines, which can now ship about 1000 bytes per second. See, e.g., {A Superhighway Shortcut}, New Orleans Times- Picayune, July 15, 1994, at B6 (giving factor of 500,000); Robert Sanford, {Test Starts on Fiber Optic Loop}, St. Louis Post- Dispatch, Oct. 8, 1994, at 9A (giving factor of 10,000). Cable TV wires can already been used for data transfers 50 times faster than those over phone lines. Paul Farhi, {Wiring Up Washington}, Wash. Post, July, 4, 1994, at WBIZ-1; {George Gilder's Telecosm}, Forbes, June 6, 1994, at 115. 27. Actually, you might even skip the recording step and instead play the music directly from a central database (just as you could today listen to music over the phone, only with much better sound quality). You might then be charged on a per-play basis rather than on a once-per-album basis. You'll still need to record the music, though, if you want to listen to it away from your infobahn connection, say in your car. And if transmission costs are high enough, you might prefer to pay them only once when you download the album, rather than every time you listen to it. 28. MiniDisc recorders/players now cost $700; DCC recorders/players cost $400. {Personal Technology: Sony's New MiniDisc Expensive But Versatile}, Atlanta J. & Const., Oct. 23, 1994, at P6; {Philips Defers DCC Intros}, Consumer Electronics, Sept. 12, 1994, at 37. Blank Minidiscs start at $14 each, blank DCCs at $8.50. Joseph Palenchar, {Sony Takes the Lead in Digital- Audio Format Battle}, Electronic Business Buyer, Nov. 1993, at 79. 29. {MiniDisc Music Promotion Pays Off, Plus High Hopes for Data Applications}, Tape-Disc Business, Sept. 1994, at 14. 30. Prices of CD players came down from about $1000 in 1983 to under $100 in 1993. James Bates, {Old Recordings Are Music to Dunhill President's Ears}, L.A. Times, Dec. 18, 1988, 4, at 9; Steve Gross, {Expo to Feature the Latest in Computer Technology}, Star Tribune, May 2, 1993, at 3D. The cost of producing CDs fell from $3.50 in 1985 to $1.75 in late 1987, and to a bit under a dollar by late 1991. See {Compact Discs; Turning Down the Volume?}, The Economist, Nov. 21, 1987, at 68 (1985 to 1987); Richard Harrington, {The Vinyl Days}, Wash. Post, Oct. 26, 1986, at F1 (giving figure of $3 as of late 1986); Kenneth Broad, {CD Clubs Offer Deals That Consumers Can't Refuse}, Billboard, Oct. 19, 1991, at 11 (1991). 31. James Flanigan, {Big Money Makes a Long-Term Bet on New Software for Electronic Teaching}, L.A. Times, May 1, 1994, at D1. 32. Barry Cooper, {Simple Needs? Try Windows Alternative}, Orlando Sentinel, Oct. 30, 1994, at H4 ("Leading Edge" IBM PC compatibles). 33. {See supra} note 22. 34. {See Funny Money}, The Economist, Sept. 10, 1994, at 74. 35. {See supra} note 9. 36. Their advice, however, will be more effective than that of reviewers today, because it will be easier for people to act on the advice. If someone reads a good review, he can instantly -- or at least not much later, if he's not near his computer at the time -- listen to the album, and, if he likes it, buy it. Today, a reader will likely forget the good review by the time he next goes to a music store. 37. {Cf.} {supra} note 23 (describing {cdconnection.com} computerized mail-order CD database, which includes both reviews from listeners, solicited by {cdconnection}, and pre-existing professional reviews). 38. While this creates a moral hazard -- the music databases want to sell as much material as possible, and might pressure reviewers to give good reviews -- the music database owners will also be keenly conscious of the information overload problem. If they give consumers reliable advice, they'll buy the material that's recommended. If the advice becomes known as unreliable, consumers might not buy at all, or buy less often than they otherwise would. 39. Some people might actually like a Top 40-type program, because they want to hear the things their peers are hearing. But even they might enjoy combining Top 40 songs with their own favorite material in some sort of custom mix. 40. Paula Bernier, {Music Choice Jams with Digital Radio}, Telephony, May 2, 1994, at 42. 41. Getting the custom-mix radio sent directly to your car will probably be too expensive. Maybe some day using wireless private lines will be as cheap as using the fiber-optics of the infobahn, but that day may be quite some time from now. 42. Note, incidentally, that if custom-mix radio gets popular enough, cars might conceivably be built to accommodate it; they might have built-in memory, and some sort of plug-in (or even wireless) downloading mechanism that can be used while the car is parked at home. (Short-distance wireless communication is cheap, which is why you don't have to pay cellular rates for your home portable phone). Note also that people who like news interspersed with their music needn't despair: Once the service becomes common, manufacturers may well sell car systems that play a recording for a while and then switch to news broadcasts. 43. {Cf.} 47 U.S.C. 317 (prohibiting "payola" -- payment to radio stations for playing particular material -- unless this is disclosed to the audience). {But see} R.H. Coase, {Payola in Radio and Television Broadcasting}, 22 J. L. & Econ. 269, 318-19 (1979) (suggesting that payola may benefit consumers). 44. This is already happening in part with online services: One leading service, Prodigy, carries intrusive advertising -- advertising that users must see, as opposed to advertising they choose to look at -- while two others, America Online and CompuServe do not. See Vic Sussman, {News of the Wired}, U.S. News & World Report, May 16, 1994, at 60. 45. 17 U.S.C. 115 (1994) (compulsory license for compositions); 37 C.F.R. 307.3, {as amended by} 58 Fed. Reg. 58282 (Nov. 1, 1993) (6.61 cents, or 1.3 cents per minute of playing time -- rounded up to the next minute -- whichever is larger). 46. 17 U.S.C. 114(b) (1994). 47. Dana Blankenhorn, {Prodigious Bulletin Boards Are Prodigy's Growing Competition}, Chi. Trib., Oct. 2, 1994, at C7 (Chicago Tribune, New York Times, and others); Hanna Liebman, {Newspapers Hit the Highway}, Mediaweek, Apr. 25, 1994, at 16 (San Jose Mercury News); Christopher Lloyd, {Are You Ready for the Future?}, London TImes, Nov. 20, 1994 (Sunday Times). 48. See Peter E. Dyson, {Publishing on the Internet for Fun and Profit}, Seybold Report on Desktop Publishing, Apr. 4, 1994, at 3; Clarinet Communications Corp., {ClariNews Public Access Newsgroups}, Autumn 1994 (on file with the author). 49. Lamont Wood, {Throwing out the Rule Book on How to Read; Project Building an On-Line Library}, Chi. Trib., Oct. 2, 1994, at C6. 50. Yardena Arar, {(Ebooks-Infoaccess.Digex.Com.) Say What?; Translation: Get a Book Via Computer in Minute}, Arizona Republic, July 14, 1994, at D1; {The Internet Bookstore Opens for Business}, Link-UP, July 1994. 51. Laurent Belsie, {Hot Competition}, Christian Science Monitor, Sept. 9, 1994, at 9. 52. There's no need to fear unsolicited "junk e-mail" arriving through this system; the home computer can easily be configured to print only those messages to which the user has actually subscribed. 53. See Bill McAllister, {Nonprofit Mail Discounts on Route to Cancellation; Thousands of Nonprofit Groups Facing Loss of Postage Subsidies}, Wash. Post, May 11, 1993, at A1. 54. Jeffrey K. MacKie-Masson & Hal Varian, {Economic FAQs About the Internet}, 8 J. Econ. Perspectives, Summer 1994, at 91. 55. Long-distance calls are expensive, but computer networks already avoid this cost by having users connect to local computers and then routing the messages across the country using their own communications mechanisms. 56. Karen E. Carney, {Saving Cash with Second-Time-Around Goods}, Inc., May 1994, at 162. 57. The L.A. Times, for instance, costs about $200 a year (for both daily and Sunday papers). Conversation with L.A. Times Subscription Department, Nov. 13, 1994. 58. See George Gilder, {Digital Dark Horse -- Newspapers}, Whole Earth Review, June 22, 1994, at 23 (describing the current state of the art, flat-screen displays about 9" wide, 12" high, and " thick, weighing a bit over a pound). 59. Highlighting and writing notes would require some sort of electronic stylus that could be used to write on the screen, but these are already available. 60. The book can easily be updated in the central database, so all future buyers will get the updated version. But it can even be updated for people who have already bought the book and downloaded it onto their ebooks. The publishers can set up a service to which any ebook owner can connect, perhaps every week or month, and automatically get updates -- for a charge -- for all the books he owns. It will be just like a pocket part for a legal treatise, but with no need to print, mail, and stuff, and no need for the reader to check both the main part and the pocket part. 61. Ebooks will also be able to support hypertext, which -- in the view of many -- is a much more useful way of organizing information than the conventional book. 62. Steven Barboza, {The Price Is Right}, Folio, May 1, 1993, at 58 (quoting John Klingel, director of new magazine development at Time Inc. Ventures). 63. Andrew M. Odlyzko, {Tragic Loss or Good Riddance? The Impending Demise of Traditional Scholarly Journals}, ___ Intern. J. Human-Computer Studies ___ (forthcoming 1995), to be reprinted in Electronic Publishing Confronts Academia: The Agenda for the Year 2000 (Robin P. Peek & Gregory B. Newby eds. 1995) (manuscript on file with author). 64. See Gilder, {supra} note 58. 65. Allen Neuharth, {The State of News Standard Today Compared With Those in the `Golden Age,'} Editor & Publisher, Feb. 26, 1994, at 54. 66. See Speech of Bruce Cohen, Director, South Africa Weekly Mail & Guardian to the First Pan-Arab Conference on Managing Newspapers in the Arab World, Sept. 28-30, 1994 (explaining the benefits of electronic distribution; the Weekly Mail & Guardian is electronically distributed), E-mail from Bruce Cohen to author, Nov. 10, 1994. 67. John McDonough, {Industry Focus}, Computer Reseller News, May 23, 1994, at 150 (NEC plans to introduce a $700 display; Sharp plans to introduce a $500 display). 68. See Ron Scherer, {Grisham, Crichton Books Serve as a Boarding Pass}, Christian Science Monitor, Sept. 2, 1993, at 14 (giving 10% figure); James Warren, {Lucrative Detours on the Information Superhighway}, Chi. Trib., Jan. 27, 1994, at 2 (giving 15% figure for hardcover books). 69. {Cf.} Alan Deutschman, {Scramble on the Information Highway}, Fortune, Feb. 7, 1994, at 129 (making a similar point); {supra} note 50 (describing current cost savings at the Internet Bookstore). 70. See, e.g., {House of Fabrics Bankruptcy News: The By- Fax Newsletter}, PR Newswire, Nov. 3, 1994 ($30 a week plus fax charges). 71. See Greg Boeck, {Hollywood Park Scene of Star Rematch}, USA Today, Dec. 10, 1993, at 7C ($364 for 6 months). 72. See Richard Vara, {Fax and Figures; Churches Utilize Popular Machines}, Houston Chronicle, Oct. 2, 1993, sec. religion, at 1. 73. See Bob von Sternberg, {Sparring in Cyberspace: Campaigns Jump on Internet}, Star Tribune, Oct. 31, 1994, at 1B. 74. Even my free e-mail system, Pegasus Mail, has such an option. 75. Each tutorial consists of 20 or so messages, of about 100 lines each; the messages, about various aspects of the Internet, are delivered every couple of days. 76. E-mail from Crispen to author, Nov. 13, 1994 (62,000 subscribers from 77 countries). 77. See Miguel Llanos, {Newbies Flock to On-Line Class of Internet Basics}, Seattle Times, Sept. 18, 1994, at D2. 78. {Pickets Can't Stop Publications; Internet, Management, Strikers Offer Own Version of News}, Houston Chronicle, Nov. 4, 1994, at A4. 79. Doug Stewart, {To Buy or Not to Buy, That Is the Question at Consumer Reports}, Smithsonian, Sept. 1993, at 34; Lesley White, Feminism with Additives}, Sunday Times, Nov. 22, 1992; See also {Cook's Magazine is Back on Shelves}, Orlando Sentinel, June 24, 1993, at H6 ({Cook's Illustrated} magazine "takes no advertising, [which] allows the staff to honestly rate and compare products"). 80. Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Lucas A. Powe, Jr., Regulating Broadcast Programming 297 (1995). 81. In fact, with the advent of new channels such as CNN, CSPAN, Discovery Channel, Nickelodeon, and so on, the Vast Wasteland critique of TV is less apt, too. 82. See George Gilder, {Breaking the Box}, National Review, Aug. 15, 1994, at 37. 83. The average major network -- ABC, CBS, and NBC -- audience in 1992 was 3 to 4 million per network in the mornings, 8 to 12 million in prime time, and 2 to 5 million in late night (11 pm to 1 am). The Leo Burnett Worldwide Advertising and Media Fact Book 489 (1994). 84. See Mitchell Kapor, {Where Is the Digital Highway Really Heading?}, Wired, July/Aug. 1993, at 53, 59, 94. 85. [F]ibre optics leapfrogs beyond the 500-channel universe, satellite dishes, wireless systems and eventually newspapers because it is a two-way system. Instead of being dependent upon a network's schedule, producer's priorities or editor's choices, consumers can pick and choose what goes on their screens just as handily as they use their telephones. . . . The information highway will be an electronic version of the book business where consumers select from tens of thousands of choices for a variety of reasons: referrals, cover designs, advertisements, word-of-mouth suggestions, publicity stunts, best-sellers' lists or review endorsements. {Cf.} Diane Francis, {Fibre Optics Leapfrogs the 500 Channels}, Financial Post, July 19, 1994 (paraphrasing Bill Gates of Microsoft). 86. See, e.g., David Lieberman, {Premiere of Video on Demand}, USA Today, Oct. 12, 1994, at 1B; Ted Bunker, {The Multimedia Infotainment I-Way}, Lan Magazine, Oct. 1994, at S24; Marc Pfeiffer, {Interactive Reality II: Video-on-Demand: Killer Application or Pie-in-the-Sky Money Pit?}, Inside Media, Sept. 21, 1994, at 74. Some of the early tests sound like something out of {The Flintstones}: When a request for a particular movie comes in, a person at the central station goes to a shelf, pulls out a video- cassette, and inserts it into a VCR that then feeds the signal to the customer's TV. Lieberman, {supra}. Obviously, this is only happening because it's a pilot project; a working system must be able to do all this automatically, and devices for implementing this have already been created. Bunker, {supra}. 87. Tom Feran, {`Make It So' `Generation' Ready for Final TV Journey,} Cleveland Plain Dealer, May 21, 1994, at 1F ({Star Trek: The Next Generation} costs over $1.6 million per hour); Ann Hodges, {Spelling Scores on All the Networks,} Houston Chronicle, Aug. 25, 1994, at 4 (Spelling's new show, {Heaven Help Us}, $1 million per hour); {TV Execs Wrangle with FCC over `Educational' Label for Kids Shows,} Memphis Commercial Appeal, June 29, 1994, at 4A (PBS's {Where in the World is Carmen Sandiego?} and {Ghostwriter} cost $390,000 per half hour); John Dempsey, {Siegel Unveils First-Run Sitcom,} Variety, Nov. 14, 1994, at 62 (proposed new sitcom called Beverly Hills Beach Club, $225,000 per half-hour). 88. In 1992, advertisers paid from $2.40 (CBS in the morning) to $9.23 (ABC prime time) per thousand viewers for a 30-second spot. Leo Burnett, {supra} note 83. Assuming about 16 commercial minutes per hour, that translates into a budget of $75,000 to almost $300,000 per million viewers for an hour-long program. Note, however, that these people needn't all be watching at once. A program that today attracts 500,000 viewers for each of its 26 regular-season episodes and 500,000 really has a viewership of 1,000,000 per episode. 89. See, e.g., {`Austin City Limits' Hits Milestone}, Billboard, Oct. 22, 1994, at 14 (country music concert show, $700,000 for a season of 13 half-hours); Diane Turbide, {Handyman's Special}, MacLean's, Mar. 28, 1994, at 61 (successful Canadian sitcom, $70,000 per half-hour); Debbi Snook, {Inquiring TV Host}, Cleveland Plain Dealer, Jan. 30, 1994, at 1H (relatively successful PBS nature show, $65,000 per season); Dan St. Ledger, {Let's Put on a Show}, Business Dateline, Apr. 25, 1993 (reality-based TV show, $40,000 per episode). 90. See Michael Crichton, {The Mediasaurus}, Wired, Sept./Oct. 1993, at 56, 58. 91. {Cf.} Michael McKeon, {Fragmenting of the News}, Wash. Post, May 11, 1994, at A21 (criticizing the "fragmented, treacherous and completely foreign communications landscape" created by "cable and interactive television, remote control, VCRs, E-Mail and faxes," in which people want their news "from like- minded people, and stated in their own terms"; this, the writer argues, leads people to "often choos[e] information delivered by demagogues appealing to fear, anxiety and prejudice through heated rhetoric and distortion"). 92. [W]e all have a shared history based on the TV pictures of the past years common to all Americans. A national memory shadowed by the same video images of Lucille Ball and Edward R. Murrow, the moon landing and the Mod Squad, Melrose Place and the nightmare-in-slow-motion that was Dallas in '63. With the advent of the new technologies, this shared history is threatened. If we all control our screens, if we can program what we watch and when for the sake of convenience, we lose this common experience in our culture. Dennis Palumbo, {Perspective on Interactive Media}, L.A. Times, July 25, 1994, at B7. The author may be overstating things, but I think there's something to what he says. 93. This is analogous to the argument that has sometimes been made about private schools, which give parents more control over their children's upbringing, but are thought by some to be dangerous to the common culture. Peter Schrag, {Kiss Our Melting- Pot Heritage Goodbye}, S.D. Union-Tribune, July 15, 1993, at B13; {cf.} Meyer v. Nebraska, 262 U.S. 390, 402 (1923) (discussing argument that ban on teaching foreign languages would "foster a homogeneous people with American ideals prepared readily to understand current discussions of civic matters"). 94. {Compare} Greg Kot, {Chilling Silence}, Chi. Trib., Dec. 27, 1992, at C12 (criticizing the apparent willingness of Time Warner Records to pressure Ice-T to drop the song {Cop Killer} from his album) {with} Jonathan Alter, {Let's Stop Crying Wolf on Censorship}, Newsweek, Nov. 29, 1993, at 67 (praising these sorts of private speech regulations as sound journalistic judgment); McCalden v. California Library Ass'n, 955 F.2d 1214 (9th Cir. 1992) (concluding that private groups' actions that pressured another group not to provide a forum for Holocaust revisionists could be tortious) {with} {id}. at 1261-62 (Kozinski, J., dissenting from denial en banc) (concluding that such pressure was itself protected by the First Amendment). See Elizabeth Venant, {An `American Psycho' Drama}, L.A. Times, Dec. 11, 1990, at E1 (describing different views of Simon & Schuster's refusal to publish Bret Easton Ellis's {American Psycho} because of its graphic depictions of dismemberment of women, and of the threatened NOW boycott of the book's next publisher); See also Brenda Herrmann, {Radio Tuning out Gangsta Rap}, Chi. Trib., Jan. 18, 1994, at C1 (discussing some radio stations' refusal to play violent or misogynistic rap songs); Stephanie Lynam, {NOW Wants Media to Cull Images Degrading Women}, Times-Picayune, Nov. 3, 1994, 13H1 (discussing proposals for boycotts of video stores that carry some slasher movies). 95. See James Warren, {Andy Rooney Suspended, But Denies Racist Comment}, Chi. Trib., Feb. 9, 1990, at C3 (describing CBS's suspension of {60 Minutes} commentator Andy Rooney for allegedly making a racist comment); UPI, Jan. 18, 1988 (describing CBS's firing of Jimmy "The Greek" Snyder on similar grounds). 96. See Jerry Schwartz, {Klan Group Forced to Disband in Atlanta Lawsuit}, Reuters, May 20, 1993. 97. See, e.g., Missouri Knights of the KKK v. Kansas City, 723 F. Supp. 1347 (W.D. Mo. 1989) (describing KKK's ultimately successful attempts to get time on a local cable system's public access channel). 98. See, e.g., Nat Hentoff, {New FCC Head Frets Sometimes over Free Speech}, Rocky Mountain News, Nov. 28, 1994, at 42A (describing complaints by FCC Chairman Reed Hundt and outgoing Speaker of the House Thomas Foley); Claudia Puig, {FCC Chief Wants Talk Radio Shows to Deal in `True Facts,'} L.A. Times, Oct. 14, 1994, at D2; Chuck Raasch, {Talk May Be Cheap, but It's Big on Radio}, Gannett News Serv., Sept. 25, 1994; Howard Kurtz, {Radio Daze}, Wash. Post, Oct. 24, 1994, at B1. 99. See Steven Weinberg, {The Kitty Kelley Syndrome; Why You Can't Always Trust What You Read in Books}, Colum. Journalism Rev., July/Aug. 1991, at 36 ("few nonfiction books are checked for accuracy[; a]s a result, inaccuracies abound"); Richard Blow & Ari Posner, {Are You Completely Bald? Adventures in Fact Checking}, The New Republic, Sept. 26, 1988, at 23 (New Republic has no fact checkers, "partly for deadline reasons, partly for financial reasons, and partly because of philosophical doubts about whether devoting limited resources to catching the kinds of things fact checking catches is the best way to serve the larger cause of printing the truth") (confirmed by author's personal conversation with the magazine's editorial department on Dec. 6, 1994). 100. {See supra} text accompanying note 33. 101. David Lieberman, {Premiere of Video on Demand}, USA Today, Oct. 12, 1994, at 1B. 102. {Cf.} {World Wide Web Draws Interest}, Tampa Tribune, Nov. 21, 1994, sec. business & finance, at 10 (U.S. Postal Service plans to put Internet kiosks in its buildings so the public can access various government agencies). 103. Expiration dates are feasible, assuming some cooperation from the ebook software. Some users might be able to avoid them by somehow tampering with the software, and underground expiration date cracking programs might become widely available. Still, it should be possible to have an expiration feature that's enforceable against the great majority of users. 104. See 17 U.S.C. 106 (1994); MAI Sys. Corp. v. Peak Computer, Inc., 991 F.2d 511, 518 (9th Cir. 1993) ("loading software into [computer memory] creates a `copy' of that software in violation of the Copyright Act"). 105. Jennifer M. Schneck, Note, {Closing the Book on the Public Lending Right}, 63 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 878, 878-80 (1989). 106. Such as the ASCAP or BMI licensing agreements that are commonly used to license the right to perform musical compositions. 107. {Cf.} Audio Home Recording Act of 1992, 17 U.S.C. 1001 {et seq.} (1994) (embodying a similar compromise, in which owners of music copyrights are compensated from sales of DAT recorders and blank DATs, and in exchange individuals are allowed to copy music for noncommercial purposes). 108. 17 U.S.C. 109(a) (1994). 109. {See supra} note 104. 110. They've made exactly this complaint about sales of used CDs. Irv Lichtman, {Songwriting Community Speaks out on Used CDs}, Sept. 4, 1993, at 16. In fact, CD distributors tried to pressure stores not to sell used CDs, steps that led to a restraint of trade lawsuit and ultimately a settlement. {Dispute Between Music Companies and Record Store Owners over Sale of Used CDs Is Settled}, Entert. L. Rep., Apr. 1994. 111. This already happens with broadcast radio stations. See, e.g., Pete Schulberg, {Portland's Radio Stations on a Roll}, Oregonian, June 12, 1994, at F1. 112. {See supra} note 79 (describing how {Consumer Reports} and {Ms.} do this today). 113. Hanna Liebman, {A Welcome Change for a Troubled Industry Predicted in New Report on Newspapers}, Mediaweek, Nov. 29, 1993, at 5. 114. Dorothy Giobbe, {The Future of Print Classifieds}, Editor & Publisher, July 16, 1994, at 24. 115. {See supra} note 102. 116. See Vic Sussman, {News of the Wired}, U.S. News & World Report, May 16, 1994, at 60. 117. {See }Aaron Zitner, {Globe to Offer New On-line Services}, Boston Globe, Dec. 7, 1994, at 49 ("publishers are concerned that competitors will cut into their print revenues by putting real estate, help wanted and other advertisements on-line [;c]lassified ads, which account for half of all Globe advertising revenues, are considered particularly vulnerable"). Newspapers can, of course, enter the classified market themselves. See Giobbe, {supra} note 114. But the newspapers won't have any substantial edge over other service providers in this field. And even if a newspaper comes up with a fabulously profitable electronic classified service, the stockholders will probably be hesitant to use this service to subsidize a money-losing print operation. 118. See Gilder, {supra} note 58; Michael Schrage, {Is Advertising Finally Dead?}, Wired, Feb. 1994, at 71, 72 (describing advertising that is both "narrowcas[t] and interactiv[e]"). This might raise complicated privacy issues (which are beyond the scope of this paper). See Cable Act of 1984, 47 U.S.C. 551 (1994) (restricting information cable operators can collect about their customers); Video Act of 1988, 18 U.S.C. 2710 (same for video stores). 119. Susan Gilmore, {`Seinfeld' or ESPN? Ads Hunt the Voters -- Big Bucks Are Bet on Those TV Spots}, Seattle Times, Nov. 4, 1994, at A1 (quoting political consultant Brett Bader). 120. {Id.} (quoting consultant Frank Greer). 121. Of course, the candidate shouldn't create ads that would be too embarassing if revealed to the public at large. For instance, in the 1990 Minnesota senatorial campaign, a letter was sent to the Jewish community on behalf of then-Sen. Rudy Boschwitz critisizing his opponent, Paul Wellstone, for marrying a non-Jew and raising his children outside the faith; the strategy appears to have backfired when the ads got a lot of press. See, e.g., Chuck Raasch, {Campaign Ads Got Nastier as Election Got Closer}, Gannett News Serv., Nov. 8, 1990. 122. The word "demassify" -- which captures extremely well what the new technologies will do to the media -- was coined (or at least popularized) by Alvin and Heidi Toffler. See Alvin Toffler & Heidi Toffler, {The Third Wave} 155 (1980); {The "Future Shock" Man Sees More Drastic Changes Ahead}, U.S. News & World Report, May 5, 1975, at 53; See also Alvin Toffler & Heidi Toffler, Creating a New Civilization: The Politics of the Third Wave (Progress & Freedom Found. 1994); Progress & Freedom Found., Cyberspace and the American Dream: A Magna Carta for the Knowledge Age rel. 1.2, at 14 (1994). 123. Anne Branscomb, ___ Yale L.J. ___ (forthcoming 1995). 124. {Compare, e.g.,} Letter of June 23, 1994 from John E. Palomino, Regional Civil Rights Director for United States Department of Education, Office of Civil Rights to Dr. Robert F. Agrella, President of Santa Rosa Junior College, at 6-7 (arguing that harassing speech in a particular academic setting was not constitutionally protected) {with} Dambrot v. Central Mich. Univ., 839 F. Supp. 477 (E.D. Mich. 1993) (striking down a university's hostile environment harassment code); Suzanne Sangree, {Title VII Prohibitions Against Hostile Environment Environment Sexual Harassment and the First Amendment: No Collision in Sight}, ___ Rutgers L.J. ___ (forthcoming 1995) (arguing workplace hostile environment harassment law is constitutional) {with} Kingsley R. Browne, {Title VII as Censorship: Hostile-Environment Harassment and the First Amendment}, 52 Ohio St. L.J. 480 (1991) (arguing the contrary) {and} Eugene Volokh, Comment, {Freedom of Speech and Workplace Harassment}, 39 UCLA L. Rev. 1791 (1992) (taking an intermediate position). 125. See Cubby, Inc. v. Compuserve Inc., 776 F. Supp. 135, 139 (S.D.N.Y. 1991) (holding, under established libel mens rea rules, that bulletin board operator can't be held liable for a defamatory posting). Electronic distribution might still lead to some adjustments in the law: As the costs of allowing replies fall, laws that require a right of reply to false defamatory material might become more viable. See Edward A. Cavazos, Note, {Computer Bulletin Board Systems and the Right of Reply}, 12 Rev. Litig. 231 (1992). 126. See John C. Scheller, Comment, {PC Peep Show: Computers, Privacy, and Child Pornography}, 27 J. Marshall L. Rev. 989 (1994). 127. Buck v. Jewell-La Salle Realty Co., 283 U.S. 191, 198-99 (1931) (holding that copyright infringement is a strict liability tort); Melville B. Nimmer & David Nimmer, Nimmer on Copyright 13.08, at 13-264 & n.2 (1994). 128. See Pinkham v. Sara Lee Corp., 983 F.2d 824, 829 (8th Cir. 1992); 3 Nimmer on Copyright, {supra} note 127, 13.08, at 13-267. 129. See Cubby, Inc. v. Compuserve Inc., 776 F. Supp. 135, 139 (S.D.N.Y. 1991) (holding that republisher of defamatory material can't be held strictly liable); Smith v. California, 361 U.S. 147 (1959) (holding that strict criminal liability for selling obscenity is impermissible); Manual Enterprises, Inc. v. Day, 370 U.S. 478 (1962) (suggesting the same in the context of civil penalties). As the Court put it in {Manual Enterprises} -- deciding whether federal law let the Post Office bar a magazine from the mails when ads in the magazine offered obscene matter for sale -- Since publishers cannot practicably be expected to investigate each of their advertisers, and since the economic consequences of an order barring even a single issue of a periodical from the mails might entail heavy financial sacrifice, a magazine publisher might refrain from accepting advertisements from those whose own materials could conceivably be deemed objectionable by the Post Office Department. This would deprive such materials, which might otherwise be entitled to constitutional protection, of a legitimate and recognized avenue of access to the public. {Id.}, at 493. The analogy to copyright infringement liability seems to me to be strong, though not perfect. See also Edward M. Di Cato, {Operator Liability Associated with Maintaining a Computer Bulletin Board}, 4 Software L.J. 147, 155-56 (1990) (advocating a mens rea of gross negligence as a minimum for holding system operators liable for copyright infringements done using their systems). {Cf.} De Acosta v. Brown, 146 F.2d 408 (2d Cir. 1944) (Hand, J., dissenting) (arguing that holding a magazine publisher liable for infringement by a contributing author "is likely to prove an appreciable and very undesirable burden upon the freedom of the press"). 130. The Supreme Court has never considered this issue, and I'm unaware of any lower courts that have discussed it at any length. 131. Even noncommercial door-to-door soliciting -- which is much more intrusive than unwanted mail or e-mail -- is constitutionally protected. {Martin} v. {City of Struthers}, 319 U.S. 141 (1943). 132. Bolger v. Youngs Drug Prods. Corp., 463 U.S. 60 (1983). This language was used in {Bolger} with regard to a content-based restriction, assertedly justified by a desire to protect householders from offensive material. Still, the argument is founded on the perceived ease of discarding unwanted mail, regardless of the reason it's not wanted. If e-mails get cheap enough that one's mailbox may have hundreds in a day, the burden of throwing them out may become too great. 133. See Trotter Hardy, {The Proper Legal Regime for "Cyberspace,"} 55 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 993, 1012-13 (1994). 134. {See also, generally,} David J. Goldstone, {The Public Forum Doctrine in the Age of the Information Superhighway}, ___ Hastings L.J. ___ (forthcoming 1995) (proposing changes to the public forum doctrine as to government-owned networks). 135. Abrams v. United States, 250 U.S. 616, 630 (1919) (Holmes, J., dissenting). 136. Whitney v. California, 274 U.S. 357, 375 (1925) (Brandeis, J., concurring). 137. Cohen v. California, 403 U.S. 15 (1971). 138. See, e.g., Turner Broadcasting, Inc. v. FCC, 113 S. Ct. 2445, 2468 (1994). 139. {Cf.} Miami Herald Co. v. Tornillo, 418 U.S. 241, 251 (1974). 140. FCC v. Pacifica Found., 438 U.S. 726, 749 (1977). 141. See {Turner Broadcasting}, 113 S. Ct. at 2458 ("the mere assertion of dysfunction or failure in a speech market, without more, is not sufficient to shield a speech regulation from [the normal strict] First Amendment standards"); {id.} at 2468 (acknowledging cable systems' "bottleneck monopoly power"); {Miami Herald}, 418 U.S. at 251, 254 (1974) (acknowledging that the high cost of publishing a newspaper "ha[s] made entry into the market- place of ideas served by the print media almost impossible," but concluding that a law that required newspapers to carry replies to attacks on candidates were still barred by "the express provisions of the First Amendment and the judicial gloss on that Amendment developed over the years"); See also Buckley v. Valeo, 424 U.S. 1 (1976) (generally rejecting arguments that wealth inequalities justify government restrictions on some speakers aimed at benefiting others). {But see} Austin v. Michigan Chamber of Commerce, 494 U.S. 652 (1990) (accepting, in the limited context of corporate expenditures aimed at benefiting political candidates, a speech restriction aimed at avoiding "the corrosive and distorting effects of immense aggregations of wealth" on the political process); FCC v. Pacifica Found., 438 U.S. 726 (1978) (accepting, in the limited context of broadcasting, a speech restriction aimed at avoiding listener offense); Red Lion Broadcasting Co. v. FCC, 395 U.S. 367 (1969) (accepting, in the limited context of broadcasting, a burden on speech justified by a concern about spectrum scarcity). Zechariah Chafee's seminal First Amendment advocacy, in fact, has been characterized as consciously accepting a willful blindness about the flaws of the speech market: "The constitutional defense of free speech, [Chafee] declared, would implicitly pretend that the distribution of economic resources did not affect the system of freedom of expression." Mark A. Graber, Transforming Free Speech 161 (1991). 142. {See Turner Broadcasting}, 113 S. Ct. at 2480-81 (O'Connor, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part); Austin v. Michigan Chamber of Commerce, 494 U.S. 652, 692 (1990) (Scalia, J., dissenting); {see also generally} Krattenmaker & Powe, {supra} note 80 (asserting that government attempts to compensate for perceived market failures in broadcasting have done more harm than good). 143. {Abrams}, 250 U.S. 616, 629 (1919) (Holmes, J., dissenting). 144. I have not discussed this last point above, but it's well-documented in other sources. {See, e.g.}, Robert Brehl, {Personal `Genie' Will Cull Masses of Data for You}, Toronto Star, Oct. 24, 1994 (describing "bozo filters," a primitive version of this); Leslie Miller, {Prodigy Guides Its Users Into Internet}, USA Today, Oct. 20, 1994, at 5D. 145. 723 F. Supp. 1347 (W.D. Mo. 1989). 146. {See supra} Part II.B.2. 147. {See supra} Part II.B.2. 148. New York Times Co. v. Sullivan, 376 U.S. 254 (1964). The protection may be in part justified by the need to protect true speech, {but see} {id.} at 279, n.19 ("[e]ven a false statement may be deemed to make a valuable contribution to public debate"), but it is nonetheless quite broad. 149. Claudia Puig, {FCC Chief Wants Talk Radio Shows to Deal in `True Facts,'} L.A. Times, Oct. 14, 1994, at D2; See also note 98 and accompanying text. 150. {Id.} 151. {Id.} 152. See, e.g., Sunstein, {supra} note 1, at 59-62. 153. {See supra} Part II.B.1. 154. {Cf.} Sunstein, {supra} note 1, at 20-21 (suggesting that people may foolishly underconsume important information about political affairs). 155. See Krattenmaker & Powe, {supra} note 80.